Skip to main content
Log in

The impact of environmental tax revenue allocation on the consequence of lobbying activities

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Economics of Governance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper investigates how a tax revenue allocation rule determines the level of environmental taxation influenced by interest groups. A model of special interest politics is modified to incorporate environmental taxation. Two groups of agents exist. The first group earns wage income, has negative utility derived from pollution generated by energy consumption, and earns a profit share of the energy industry. The second group earns wages and has negative utility from pollution, but does not own shares. The government imposes an ad-valorem pollution tax and spends a proportion of its revenue as compensation for the tax burden on the first group and the remainder on public abatement. Two regimes are considered. First, a resource-rent group lobbies the government to protect its income source. Second, an environmentally conscious group lobbies the government to spend the revenue for pollution reduction. The critical proportion of transfer to tax revenue is derived to achieve the socially optimal rate of environmental taxation, even when the tax rate is subject to the influence of interest groups.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See studies such as Damania and Fredriksson (2003) and Ono (2009).

  2. Millock and Nauges (2006) mentioned that in the case of the Swedish emission tax on \(NO_{x}\), the revenue is rebated to industries based on their energy consumption. Additionally, carbon tax rates are often reduced for energy-intensive industries in EU countries and in Japan. These options can be considered as tax burden compensation that could benefit energy-rent holders.

  3. In this model, lobby formation is exogenous to focus on the impact of tax revenue allocation on environmental policy. Those who are interested in the relationship between environmental policy and endogenous lobby formation should consult studies, such as Damania and Fredriksson (2003) and Kawahara (2014).

  4. Following Gulati (2008), we assume that, if one group of agents is unorganized, the other group of agents are perfectly organized. However, we could assume that the group of agents is partially organized. Let the share of agents in each group organized as a lobby be \(\theta ^{j}\in [0,1]\) and assume that \(\theta ^{-j}=0\text { if }\theta ^{j}>0\). The welfare function without contribution for organized members of the group \(\omega _{j}^{\theta }(\tau )\) is provided by multiplying the share of the organized group \(\theta ^{j}\) by the gross welfare function for all the members of the group without contribution \(\omega _{j}(\tau )\), that is, \(\omega _{j}^{\theta }(\tau )=\theta ^{j}\omega _{j}(\tau )\). The problem of the government could be \(\tilde{G_{j}}=\beta ^{j}\omega _{j}(\tau )+\beta \omega _{-j}(\tau )\), where \(\beta ^{j}=(1-\beta )\theta ^{j}+\beta <1\). In this setting, under the regime with lobbying by agents in the resource-rent group, the difference between the optimal and the equilibrium tax rates with lobbying by the resource-rent group could be derived as \({\tilde{\Theta }}_{R}\equiv \tilde{\tau ^{o}}-\tilde{\tau _{R}^{*}}=(1-{\tilde{\lambda }}_{R})\Omega\), where \({\tilde{\lambda }}_{R}=[(1-\beta )\theta ^{R}+\beta ]r+\beta n(<1)\) and \(\Omega\) is the same as in the original model. This equation implies that our results are not qualitatively changed if some of the agents in the organized group are unorganized.

References

  • Aghion P, Howitt P (2009) The economics of growth. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Aidt TS (1998) Political internalization of economic externalities and environmental policy. J Public Econ 69(1):1–16

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aidt TS (2010) Green taxes: refunding rules and lobbying. J Environ Econ Manage 60(1):31–43

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anesi V (2006) Earmarked taxation and political competition. J Public Econ 90(4–5):679–701

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumol W, Oates W (1988) The theory of environmental policy, 2nd edn. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bovenberg AL (1999) Green tax reforms and the double dividend: an updated reader’s guide. Int Tax Public Finance 6(3):421–443

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brett C, Keen M (2000) Political uncertainty and the earmarking of environmental taxes. J Public Econ 75(3):315–340

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Damania R, Fredriksson PG (2003) Trade policy reform, endogenous lobby group formation, and environmental policy. J Econ Behav Organ 52(1):47–69

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fredriksson PG (1997) The political economy of pollution taxes in a small open economy. J Environ Econ Manage 33(1):44–58

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerlagh R, van der Zwaan B (2003) Gross world product and consumption in a global warming model with endogenous technological change. Resour Energy Econ 25(1):35–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goulder LH (1995) Environmental taxation and the double dividend: a reader’s guide. Int Tax Public Finance 2(2):157–183

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman GM, Helpman E (1994) Protection for sale. Am Econ Rev 84(4):833–850

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman GM, Helpman E (2001) Special interest politics. The MIT press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Gulati S (2008) Free trade and the burden of domestic policy. Can J Econ/Revue canadienne d’économique 41(3):817–837

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Habla W, Roeder K (2013) Intergenerational aspects of ecotax reforms—an application to Germany. J Environ Econ Manag 66:301–318

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Habla W, Winkler R (2013) Political influence on non-cooperative international climate policy. J Environ Econ Manag 66:219–234

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lai YB (2007) The optimal distribution of pollution rights in the presence of political distortions. Environ Resource Econ 36:367–388

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lai YB (2008) Auctions or grandfathering: the political economy of tradable emission permits. Public Choice 136:181–200

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kawahara S (2014) Endogenous lobby formation and endogenous environmental protection with unilateral tariff reduction. Environ Resource Econ 57(1):41–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marsiliani L, Renstrom TI (2000) Time inconsistency in environmental policy: tax earmarking as a commitment solution. Econ J 110(462):123–138

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Millock K, Nauges C (2006) Ex post evaluation of an earmarked tax on air pollution. Land Econ 82(1):68–84

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ministry of Economy, Trade and Industry, Japan. Outline of budget proposal for resource and energy-related operations in fiscal 2017. 2017

  • Ministry of the Environment, Japan. Greening of whole tax system and carbon tax in Japan. 2017

  • Ono T (2009) The political economy of environmental and social security policies: the role of environmental lobbying. Econ Gov 10(3):261–296

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pigou AC (1920) The economics of welfare. Macmillan, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Schleich J, Orden D (2000) Environmental quality and industry protection with noncooperative versus cooperative domestic and trade policies. Rev Int Econ 8(4):681–697

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williams III RC (2016) Environmental taxation. NBER Working Paper 22303

Download references

Acknowledgements

The author is grateful to Marko Köthenbürger (co-editor) for his informative advice and thanks to two anonymous referees for their constructive comments and suggestions. This work is supported by a Grant-in-Aid for Scientific Research(C)17K03682 from the Japan Society for the Promotion of Science. Any errors are the sole responsibility of the author.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Minoru Nakada.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix A: Comparison between Optimal And Equilibrium Tax Rates

Consider regime (1) wherein the resource-rent group contributes. Let the difference between the optimal and the equilibrium tax rates be

$$\begin{aligned} \Theta _{R}\equiv \tau ^{o}-\tau _{R}^{*}=(1-\lambda _{R})\Omega , \end{aligned}$$

where

$$\begin{aligned} \Omega= & {} \alpha v_{p}\left[ \phi +(1-\alpha )(1-\eta )(1-2\phi )\right] +(1-\alpha )\left[ (1-\alpha )(1-\eta )-\phi \right] , \end{aligned}$$

and \(0<\lambda _{R}=r+\beta n<1\). To ensure that the equilibrium tax rate \(\tau _{R}^{*}\) is equal to the optimum \(\tau ^{o}\) (consequently, \(\Theta _{R}=0\)), let the critical proportion of transfer to tax revenue be

$$\begin{aligned} {\bar{\phi }}=\frac{(1-\alpha )(1-\eta )\left[ \alpha v_{p}+(1-\alpha )\right] }{(1-\alpha ) -\alpha v_{p}\left[ 1-2(1-\alpha )(1-\eta )\right] }. \end{aligned}$$

\(\Omega \gtreqless 0\) if \(\phi \lesseqgtr {\bar{\phi }}\). Since \(\beta <1\), we have \(\tau ^{o}>\tau _{R}^{*}\) if \(\phi <{\bar{\phi }}\) or \(\tau ^{o}<\tau _{R}^{*}\) if \(\phi >{\bar{\phi }}\). Next, consider regime (2) wherein the environmentally conscious group contributes. Let the difference between the equilibrium and the optimal tax rates be

$$\begin{aligned} \Theta _{N}\equiv \tau _{N}^{*}-\tau ^{o}=(\lambda _{N}-\beta )\Omega , \end{aligned}$$

where \(\lambda _{N}=\beta r+n=\beta -n(\beta -1)>\beta\). Similarly, we have \(\tau _{N}^{*}>\tau ^{o}\) if \(\phi <{\bar{\phi }}\) or \(\tau _{N}^{*}<\tau ^{o}\) if \(\phi >{\bar{\phi }}\). Finally, in result (3), \(\Omega =0\) if \(\phi ={\bar{\phi }}\): then, we find \(\Theta _{R}=\Theta _{N}=0\) and \(\tau ^{o}=\tau _{R}^{*}=\tau _{N}^{*}\).

Appendix B: Effects of changes in the proportion of transfer to tax revenue on convergence

As for result (1), consider the regime with lobbying by the resource-rent group. We differentiate the difference between the optimal and equilibrium tax rates (18) with respect to the proportion of transfer to revenue parameter \(\phi\) as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \Theta _{R}}{\partial \phi }=-(1-\lambda _{R})\left\{ (1-\alpha )-\alpha v_{p}\left[ 1-2(1-\alpha )(1-\eta )\right] \right\} <0, \end{aligned}$$

if the curly brackets are positive or \(H=\frac{1}{1-\eta }<2(1-\alpha )\frac{\alpha v_{p}}{\alpha (v_{p}+1)-1}\) as long as \(v_{p}>\frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha }\). The above inequality indicates that an increase in \(\phi\) makes the divergence between the optimum and the equilibrium smaller when the energy resource sector is fairly concentrated and the marginal damage of pollution is sufficiently high. Similarly, for result (2) under the regime with lobbying by the environmentally conscious group, if we differentiate (19) with respect to \(\phi\), we have

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \Theta _{N}}{\partial \phi }=-(\lambda _{N}-\beta )\left\{ (1-\alpha )-\alpha v_{p}\left[ 1-2(1-\alpha )(1-\eta )\right] \right\} <0, \end{aligned}$$

and find the same result as in result (1).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Nakada, M. The impact of environmental tax revenue allocation on the consequence of lobbying activities. Econ Gov 21, 335–349 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10101-020-00243-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10101-020-00243-6

Keywords

Mathematics Subject Classification

Navigation