Skip to content
Publicly Available Published by De Gruyter March 24, 2022

Labor Share Dynamics and Factor Complementarity

  • Juin-Jen Chang and Chun-Hung Kuo ORCID logo EMAIL logo

Abstract

This paper investigates the mechanism behind the cyclical movements in the labor income share. We build a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model with search and matching frictions to examine the counter-cyclicality and overshooting of the labor income share, following a technology innovation. This model features (i) a time-varying output elasticity of labor, generated from the capital–labor complementarity under a constant-elasticity-of-substitution production function, and (ii) an endogenous markup variation, generated from wage/price rigidity. Through the output elasticity and markup channels, the capital–labor complementarity interacts with wage rigidity, which allows us to produce a satisfactory matching of the amplitude of the labor share overshooting observed in the data. The amplitude of the labor share overshooting is more significant when wages (prices) are more (less) sticky, and when the government’s interest rate rule is more (less) responsive to the deviation in the inflation (output) target.

JEL Classification: E24; E25; E31; E32

1 Introduction

US evidence suggests that the labor income share (LIS) displays two distinctive features: counter-cyclicality and overshooting.[1] In response to a positive technology shock, the LIS falls on impact, moving counter-cyclically with output; it then reverts and increases over time, exhibiting a hump-shaped response and overshooting its initial level. As shown in Figure 1 repeated from Ríos-Rull and Santaeulàlia-Llopis (2010), the LIS overshoots its initial level at around the fifth quarter after the technology shock, and the overshooting is about 0.2% at the peak around the 18th quarter. This empirical evidence is difficult to reconcile with the standard real business cycle (RBC) models. While some recent studies have investigated this discrepancy, it is still an understudied research topic. Economists have yet to provide an acceptable theoretical explanation for the pattern of labor shares over the business cycle.

Figure 1: 
Empirical impulse response functions of the LIS to productivity innovations in the US.
Figure 1:

Empirical impulse response functions of the LIS to productivity innovations in the US.

This paper attempts to understand the mechanism behind the cyclical movements in the LIS. We thoroughly account for both the counter-cyclicality of the LIS and its overshooting behavior by shedding light on (i) the capital–labor complementarity under a constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) production function, and (ii) the wage/price rigidity in imperfectly competitive product and labor markets. Our workhorse is a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) model in which the labor market is frictional à la the Diamond–Mortensen–Pissarides (DMP) model, and the product market is monopolistically competitive. In the DSGE model, the capital–labor complementarity interacts with wage/price rigidity, and the interaction governs the LIS dynamics.

Adopting a CES production function is a natural step in understanding the LIS dynamics.[2] The empirical evidence has shown that a Cobb-Douglas (CD) production function is at odds with the substantial cyclical fluctuations observed in factor shares,[3] which support a value significantly below unity at standard frequencies, ranging between 0.5 and 0.8 (see León-Ledesma, McAdam, and Willman (2010, 2015). The substitution elasticity is even smaller when estimated using a low-frequency panel model, being around 0.4 (Chirinko and Mallick 2017), and from micro (firm or industry) cross-sections, ranging between 0.3 and 0.5 (Raval 2019). However, most RBC models assume a CD production function, which leads to a constant output elasticity of labor (capturing the wedge between the marginal and average product of labor). Thus, the LIS displays no cyclical dynamics, since the real wage equals the marginal product of labor and moves proportionally with the average product of labor. By contrast, under a CES production function the capital–labor complementarity implies a time-varying output elasticity of labor, which depends on the capital–labor ratio.

Imperfect product and labor markets are also empirically relevant. Arpaia, Párez, and Pichelmann (2009) have shown that market imperfections provide important explanatory power to movements in the LIS. Under an imperfect labor market, wages are non-competitive, depending on the bargaining between the employer and the employee along with the matching friction (Pissarides 1990). Under an imperfect product market, the firms’ monopoly power over pricing produces a markup of price over marginal cost, which lowers the wage paid to workers (Benhabib and Farmer 1994). Imperfections in the labor and product markets jointly govern the dynamics of real wages, labor hours, employment (unemployment), output, and hence the LIS. In our model, the rigidity in wages and prices, stressed by New Keynesian (NK) models, is properly considered: wage rigidity leads to a sluggish response of the wage to business cycles, and price rigidity leads to an endogenous markup.[4] These two rigidities simultaneously affect the time-varying output elasticity and markup, thereby enabling our model to explain the LIS dynamics.

The output elasticity of labor channel and the markup channel are key to the analysis. The LIS increases with the output elasticity of labor (since a higher output elasticity implies a lower average product of labor), but decreases with the price markup (since a higher markup leads to a lower wage rate). Through these two channels, our theoretical model can fully characterize the LIS dynamics in terms of the counter-cyclicality and overshooting. Our calibrated model generates proper impulse responses, which match the empirical finding of Ríos-Rull and Santaeulàlia-Llopis (2010) reasonably well, compared with existing studies.

Why does the LIS move counter-cyclically on impact? In response to a positive technology shock, both the marginal products of labor hours and capital increase. Labor hours immediately increase, but the predetermined capital remains unchanged on impact; this discrepancy in factor adjustment leads to a decrease in the capital–labor ratio. Since capital and labor are relatively complementary in the US, a lower capital–labor ratio reduces the output elasticity of labor, giving rise to a negative effect on the LIS. In addition, because of the capital–labor complementarity, the upward jump in labor greatly raises the rental rate of capital. As factor prices rise, the real marginal cost increases and the price markup decreases. Since wage/price stickiness depresses the markup channel, the output elasticity channel dominates, leading to the counter-cyclicality of the LIS on impact.

Why does the LIS overshoot in transition? While the upward jump in labor hours increases the rental rate of capital on impact, the increment steadily decreases in transition. By contrast, capital greatly increases after the impact, which raises the wage rate in transition until the marginal product of labor eventually diminishes. It turns out that in transition the wage-rental ratio exhibits a hump-shaped response to a positive technology shock. Under the CES production with factor complementarity, this hump-shaped response translates into a similar pattern in the capital–labor ratio and hence the output elasticity of labor, resulting in the LIS overshooting. In short, with factor complementarity, asymmetric adjustment speeds of capital and labor produce the LIS dynamics both in terms of the counter-cyclicality and overshooting. Wage rigidity then amplifies this adjustment asymmetry between capital and labor, resulting in a more responsive overshooting of the LIS. In the presence of sticky wages, the timing of the increase in wages is postponed so that in transition wages increase less, but labor hours increase more. As a result, the capital–labor ratio is lower at the beginning of the transition, but it becomes higher in the later periods of the transition. Wage rigidity thus reinforces the output elasticity channel, leading to a more pronounced LIS overshooting.

Since the seminal work of Ríos-Rull and Santaeulàlia-Llopis (2010), the empirical impulse responses of the LIS have motivated many studies to examine the LIS dynamics under various versions of the DMP search model.[5] Choi and Ríos-Rull (2009) find that the LIS dynamics are better explained by the non-unit elasticity of substitution between labor and capital than the labor market frictions. Although Choi and Ríos-Rull (2009) persuasively argue the importance of labor-capital complementarity, in their model the magnitude of the LIS overshooting is very limited. Their model implies that the LIS overshooting is merely 0.02% relative to the initial level, but for the US data the overshooting is about 0.2% at the peak. As stressed by Choi and Ríos-Rull (2009), it is however still difficult to fully capture the overshooting property even under a CES production function. By accounting for the interaction between the capital–labor complementarity and wage rigidity, our model can generate more responsive LIS overshooting. Our calibration results show that the magnitude of the LIS overshooting is around 0.17%, which is closer to the magnitude in the data. Moreover, the LIS overshoots its initial level at around the sixth or seventh quarter after the shock, and reaches its peak in the 17th quarter, all of which match the data better. To generate the overshooting property of the LIS, León-Ledesma and Satchi (2019) use a production function with a non-constant elasticity of substitution between capital and labor. This non-constant substitution elasticity is lower in the short run than in the long run, which amplifies the LIS overshooting. In a way that differs from León-Ledesma and Satchi (2019), Koh and Santaeulàlia-Llopis (2017) generate the LIS overshooting by assuming a production function with a non-constant elasticity of substitution between labor and capital in the short run, and a CD production function in the long run. Our model contributes to the literature by showing that the interaction between the capital–labor complementarity and wage/price rigidity can adequately explain the empirical LIS overshooting without resorting to a sophisticated non-constant-substitution-elasticity production function.

While wage rigidity amplifies the LIS overshooting, price rigidity attenuates it. With price rigidity, markups are time-varying and pro-cyclical to output in transition, making the LIS overshooting less pronounced. In our model, price and wage rigidities play quite distinct roles from the way they behavior in Colciago and Rossi (2015) and Reicher (2016). In the absence of capital–labor complementarity, Colciago and Rossi (2015) consider strategic interactions among an endogenous number of producers à la Bilbiie, Ghironi, and Melitz (2012), and show that the counter-cyclical markup is fundamental in addressing the LIS overshooting, whereas real wage rigidity is not crucial. Similarly, under a CD production function, Reicher (2016) considers staggered wage bargaining à la Gertler and Trigari (2009) and shows that nominal wage stickiness does not lead the LIS to overshoot. By contrast, our results show that wage rigidity interacts with the capital–labor complementarity, which produces a better matching of the amplitude of the labor share overshooting observed in the data even in the absence of the markup channel (by shutting off the price rigidity).

We also compare the variance of the LIS and the LIS-output correlation with the empirical counterparts. The current empirical evidence indicates that the LIS is counter-cyclical. The estimated correlation coefficients between the LIS and output range between −0.13 (estimated by Choi and Ríos-Rull 2009) and −0.34 (estimated by Koh and Santaeulàlia-Llopis 2017). In our model, the LIS-output correlation is −0.18, which is located well within the range of the estimates. It is worth noting that the negative correlation between the LIS and output cannot be produced without the rigidity of wages and prices.

Finally, we examine how the government’s demand-side monetary policy interacts with the supply-side technology shock in the NK model. We find that the LIS overshooting becomes more pronounced if the government’s interest rate rule is more responsive to the deviation in the inflation target, but it becomes less pronounced if the government’s interest rate rule is more responsive to the deviation in the output target. A more active inflation-targeting policy restrains the downward trend of real marginal costs caused by a technological advance, resulting in relatively low markups. Since lower markups are associated with higher labor shares, the LIS overshooting becomes more pronounced via the markup channel. By contrast, the government’s output-targeting policy affects the LIS dynamics mainly through the output elasticity channel. When the stabilization effect of the demand-side policy restrains the supply-side output expansion, the output elasticity channel becomes weaker, decreasing the extent to which the LIS overshoots.

This paper is also related to two recent studies. Shao and Silos (2013) consider the sunk cost of entry in a DMP model with a CD production function and constant markups, which generates sluggishness in the entry decision of firms and the counter-cyclicality of vacancies. The counter-cyclicality of vacancies causes the efficiency of the factors of production to rise in booms, accelerating the entry of firms. As a result, the LIS has a more pronounced and persistent response to the technology shock, leading to the LIS overshooting consequence. Instead, by highlighting factor complementarity and endogenous markups, our model can generate a pronounced LIS overshooting as the empirical finding, even though vacancies are pro-cyclical, as in a standard DMP model. Mangin and Sedláček (2018) feature direct competition between heterogeneous firms in hiring workers. Through firm competition in hiring, technology shocks have a cohort effect on labor contracts. This cohort effect is more pronounced in transition, pushing up the aggregate wage payment and resulting in the overshooting of the LIS. In the Mangin and Sedláček (2018) model, new entrant firms cannot adjust their capital stock once it has settled down, even though the technology level changes. This restriction excludes the role of the labor-capital complementarity in explaining the LIS dynamics.[6]

2 The Model

There are three sectors in the model economy: households, firms, and a government. The household sector consists of a large number of identical households. Each household has a continuum of members of measure one; some members are employed and the others are unemployed. In the firm sector, there are three types of firms: final-good firms, intermediate-good pricing firms, and intermediate-good producing firms. The government balances its budget. Time is discrete.

2.1 The Labor Market

The labor market is frictional in the sense that a job seeker and a firm with a vacant position have to go through a time-consuming search process to form a match. Following Pissarides (1990), we assume that the number of matches m t depends on the number of unemployed workers (job seekers) u t and vacancies v t :

m t = γ m u t ξ v t 1 ξ ,

where γ m > 0 is the matching efficiency, and ξ is the matching elasticity with respect to unemployment. An unemployed worker finds a job with probability fu,t = m t /u t , and a vacant position gets filled with probability fv,t = m t /v t . Both the job-finding and vacancy-filling rates are taken as given by households and firms. The labor market tightness is defined as θ t = v t /u t . The number of employed workers evolves according to nt+1 = (1 − s)n t + m t , for newly-formed matches become productive in the next period, and all employed workers are subject to exogenous separation with probability s.

2.2 The Household Sector

The expected lifetime utility of the representative household is given by

(1) E 0 t = 0 β t c t 1 γ c 1 1 γ c Ψ n t h t 1 + γ h 1 + γ h ,

where E 0 is the expectation operator conditional on the period 0 information set, and 0 < β < 1 is the subjective discount factor. The representative household consists of a continuum of household members. While the family members are subject to unemployment risk, they insure each other. Therefore, each household member, either employed or unemployed, has the same consumption level c t .[7] γ c > 0 measures the inter-temporal elasticity of consumption. The household’s labor supply is considered at both the extensive (employment, n t ) and intensive margins (hours per worker, h t ), and γ h > 0 measures the Frisch elasticity of labor supply at the intensive margin. Ψ captures the weight of labor in the utility function.

The household receives dividends Π t from the firm sector and pays a lump-sum tax T t to the government. Each employed member earns real wages w t , while each unemployed member receives unemployment benefits z from the government. Thus, the household’s budget constraint, in units of period t final goods, is given by

c t + i t + b t = w t h t n t + ( 1 n t ) z + r k , t K t + R t 1 b t 1 π t + Π t T t ,

where Rt−1 is the gross nominal interest rate, bt−1 is the stock of real government bonds at the beginning of period t, and π t p t /pt−1 is the gross inflation of the nominal price p t of final goods. Given the real rental rate rk,t and the capital stock K t at the beginning of period t, the household accumulates its capital by investing i t so that

K t + 1 = ( 1 δ ) K t + i t ,

where δ is the depreciation rate of capital.

To maximize its lifetime utility, the household chooses sequences of consumption, investment, the capital stock, and government bonds, subject to the budget constraint and the capital evolution equation. The first-order conditions are as follows:

(2) c t γ c = λ t ,
(3) λ t = β E t λ t + 1 R t π t + 1 ,
(4) λ t = β E t λ t + 1 r k , t + 1 + ( 1 δ ) .

where λ t is the Lagrange multiplier of the budget constraint.

2.2.1 Value Functions of Household Members

In units of period t final goods, the value of an employed worker for the household is characterized by

W t = w t h t Ψ λ t h t 1 + γ h 1 + γ h + β E t λ t + 1 λ t ( 1 s ) W t + 1 + s U t + 1 ,

where w t h t is the real labor income, and Ψ λ t h t 1 + γ h 1 + γ h measures the disutility of working h hours. The last term on the right-hand side is the continue value of the employed worker, indicating that an employed worker might separate from her employer with probability s and receive the unemployment asset value, U t + 1 . Since an unemployed worker receives unemployment benefit z, the value of an unemployed worker in period t is characterized by

U t = z + β E t λ t + 1 λ t f u , t W t + 1 + ( 1 f u , t ) U t + 1 .

The last term on the right-hand side captures the continue value of being unemployed, taking into account the fact that an unemployed worker becomes employed with probability fu,t. We define the net surplus of employed workers as N t W t U t , leading to

N t = w t h t Ψ λ t h t 1 + γ h 1 + γ h z + β E t λ t + 1 λ t ( 1 s f u , t ) N t + 1 .

2.3 The Firm Sector

The firm sector, as mentioned earlier, consists of three different types of firms: final-good firms, intermediate-good pricing firms, and intermediate-good producing firms. In line with Trigari (2006) and Thomas (2008), we divide the intermediate-good sector into producing and pricing firms. A producing firm hires a worker and rents capital to produce homogeneous goods, which are sold to pricing firms. Pricing firms transform the purchased homogeneous products into heterogeneous ones, and they exercise their market power to set the desired prices. Pricing firms sell their products to the final-good firms. It is convenient to look at this production process backward.

2.3.1 Final-good Firms

In a perfectly competitive market, a representative final-good firm produces final goods y t according to the following production function:

y t = 0 1 y j , t ϵ 1 ϵ d j ϵ ϵ 1 ,

where yj,t refers to the heterogeneous intermediate goods purchased from the pricing firm j ∈ [0, 1], and ϵ > 1 measures the elasticity of substitution between different intermediate goods. Taking the prices of final goods p t and intermediate goods pj,t as given, the final good-firm demands intermediate good yj,t according to

(5) y j , t = p j , t p t ϵ y t ,

where p t = 0 1 p j , t 1 ϵ d j 1 1 ϵ .

2.3.2 Intermediate-Good Pricing Firms

A pricing firm purchases homogeneous intermediate goods at price φ t from producing firms in a competitive market. One unit of homogeneous intermediate goods is transformed into one unit of heterogeneous ones. A pricing firm chooses the desired nominal price pj,t, subject to price-adjustment costs à la Rotemberg (1982).[8] Thus, the profit-maximization problem of the pricing firm can be expressed as

max p j , t E 0 t = 0 β t λ t λ 0 p j , t p t y j , t φ t y j , t ψ p 2 p j , t p j , t 1 π 1 2 y t ,

subject to the demand function of the intermediate good yj,t (5). Given the steady-state gross inflation π ≥ 1, ψ p ≥ 0 measures the extent of price stickiness. Households own equity in the intermediate-good pricing firms, and the period t discount factor is, therefore, β t λ t λ 0 .

Our analysis focuses on a symmetric equilibrium, and the subscript j can thus be removed hereafter. Accordingly, the first-order condition with respect to pj,t is simplified to the following equation:

(6) 1 ψ p π t π 1 π t π + β E t λ t + 1 λ t ψ p π t + 1 π 1 π t + 1 π y t + 1 y t = ϵ ( 1 φ t ) .

Given that intermediate goods are the only input for producing final goods, the real price φ t equals the real marginal cost of a pricing firm. Thus, a pricing firm’s price-cost markup is simply the inverse of the real marginal cost, i.e., μ t = 1/φ t .

2.3.3 Intermediate-Good Producing Firms

To produce intermediate goods, the representative producing firm hires a worker, working h hours, and rents capital k t from the household sector. In particular, the production function of the producing firm takes the following CES form:

(7) x t = F ( k t , h t ) = A t α k t σ 1 σ + ( 1 α ) h t σ 1 σ ϑ σ σ 1 ,

where 0 < σ < ∞ is the elasticity of substitution between labor hours and capital, α is a distributional parameter, and ϑ > 0 measures the extent of the returns to scale of production. A t denotes the time-varying technology, which is common across the producing firms, and it evolves according to the following first-order autoregressive process:

ln A t = ( 1 ρ A ) ln A + ρ A ln A t 1 + ε A , t , ε A , t N 0 , σ A 2 ,

where ɛA,t is an i.i.d innovation.

2.3.4 Value Functions of Producing Firms

Since a producing firm provides exactly one job position, the firm’s value depends on whether the job position is filled or not. Denote J t as the filled job’s asset value and V t as the vacant job’s asset value, respectively. A filled job’s asset value is characterized by

J t = max k t , h t φ t F ( k t , h t ) w t h t r k , t k t + β E t λ t + 1 λ t ( 1 s ) J t + 1 + s V t + 1 ,

where φ t is the price of a producing firm’s products. The last term on the right-hand side captures the continue value, given that an existing match could break down with probability s. Taking the real wage rate w t and capital rental rate rk,t as given, a producing firm chooses h t and k t , yielding the following first-order conditions:

(8) w t = φ t m p h t = φ t ( 1 α ) ϑ A t α k t h t σ 1 σ + 1 α ϑ σ σ 1 1 h t ϑ 1 ,
(9) r k , t = φ t m p k t = φ t α ϑ A t α k t h t σ 1 σ + 1 α ϑ σ σ 1 1 h t ϑ 1 k t h t 1 σ ,

where mpk t and mph t are the marginal product of capital and of labor hours, respectively. These two first-order conditions imply the following relationship

(10) k t h t = α 1 α w t r k , t σ ,

indicating that the equilibrium capital–labor ratio k t / h t is governed by the relative factor price w t / r t . It can be clearly seen that the capital–labor ratio is more sensitive to changes in the relative factor price if the elasticity of substitution between capital and labor σ is larger.

Moreover, a vacant job’s asset value is characterized by

V t = κ + β E t λ t + 1 λ t f v , t J t + 1 + ( 1 f v , t ) V t + 1 ,

where κ is the cost of providing a vacant job position. The continue value shows that a vacant job gets filled with probability fv,t.

As in the standard search and matching models, producing firms enter and exit the labor market freely so that V t = 0 for all t. Accordingly, we have the job creation condition as follows:

(11) κ f v , t = β E t λ t + 1 λ t φ t + 1 F ( k t + 1 , h t + 1 ) w t + 1 h t + 1 r k , t + 1 k t + 1 + ( 1 s ) κ f v , t + 1 ,

where the left-hand side is the expected cost of filling a vacancy, and the right-hand side captures the discounted marginal benefit of having a filled position.

2.4 Determination of Wages and Labor Income Share

An employed worker and her employer bargain over wages, while the employer retains unilateral control over the employee’s working hours. This so-called right-to-manage bargaining, as argued by Trigari (2006) and Christoffel and Kuester (2008), is a more realistic description of labor contracts. Under such an arrangement, the working hours will always remain on the labor demand curve. This implication is different from that of hours bargaining and allows us to easily compare our results with those in the perfectly competitive labor market.[9]

Let η be the worker’s bargaining power. The equilibrium (hourly) wage rate is determined by solving the Nash bargaining problem. That is,

w t Nash = arg max w t N t η J t 1 η ,

subject to the employer’s hours demand function (10). Accordingly, we can obtain the real wage income w t Nash h t as follows:

(12) w t Nash h t = χ t φ t x t r k , t k t + κ θ t + ( 1 χ t ) Ψ λ t h t 1 + γ h 1 + γ h + z + χ t 1 1 χ t 1 χ t + 1 χ t + 1 χ t κ f v , t 1 s f u , t ,

where

χ t = η 1 Ω t η 1 Ω t + ( 1 η ) .
χ t can be thought of as the adjusted (time-varying) bargaining power of a worker, with Ω t σ 1 m r s t φ t m p h t being a measure of deviation from efficient hours and m r s t = Ψ h t γ h / λ t being the marginal rate of substitution between consumption and hours.

Hall (2005) and Shimer (2005) argue that flexible wages may not reconcile with the magnitude of unemployment volatility. To investigate the role played by the (real) wage rigidity, we follow Hall (2005) and Blanchard and Galí (2010) and assume that the prevailing real wage follows

w t = w t norm ψ w w t Nash 1 ψ w , 0 ψ w 1 ,

where w t norm represents the wage norm, which is the bargained wage in the previous period. Thus, ψ w measures the degree of wage rigidity; a higher ψ w refers to a stronger wage stickiness.

2.4.1 Labor Income Share (LIS)

Given that y t is the real total income, the labor income share is

S l , t = w t l t y t = w t a p h t .

To derive the above equation, we have used the relations l t = n t h t , y t = n t x t , and aph t = x t /h t . Under the CES production function (7), the average product of labor is

(13) a p h t = m p h t 1 Φ t ; Φ t = ϑ ( 1 α ) α k t h t σ 1 σ + ( 1 α ) .

where the wedge between average and marginal labor productivity Φ t is the output elasticity of labor. Note that if σ → 1, the CES production function (7) atrophies to the CD one with a homogeneous degree of ϑ, and the output elasticity of labor becomes a constant Φ t = ϑ(1 − α).

The Nash wage bargaining solution satisfies (8) since the solution under the right-to-manage bargain lies on the labor demand curve. Given (8) with μ t = 1/φ t and (13), the labor income share can be further expressed as

(14) S l , t = w t a p h t = φ t m p h t m p h t 1 Φ t = Φ t μ t .
Equation (14) indicates that the LIS increases with the output elasticity of labor Φ t (which captures the wedge between average and marginal labor productivity), but it decreases with the price markup μ t (which captures the wedge between the wage rate and the marginal labor productivity). The output elasticity of labor measures the sensitivity of output in response to labor, and hence a larger Φ t leads to a higher labor income share. To be more specific, (13) shows that the output elasticity of labor Φ t is increasing (decreasing) in the capital–labor ratio (k t /h t ) if capital and labor are relatively complementary, 0 < σ < 1 (substitutable, 1 < σ < ∞), because capital raises (lowers) the output elasticity of labor. In addition, a higher markup allows firms to exercise their monopoly power to raise prices by reducing output. To lower the output level, the labor demand declines, pulling down wages, i.e., w t = φ t mph t with φ t = 1/μ t < 1, as shown in (8). Thus, the LIS decreases with the price markup μ t .

2.5 The Government Budget and Aggregate Resource Constraints

The government levies a lump-sum tax T t and issues bonds to finance unemployment benefits. The government budget constraint is given by

z ( 1 n t ) + R t 1 b t 1 π t = T t + b t .

In addition, the government (the monetary authority) follows an interest rate rule (Taylor’s rule) as follows:

ln R t R = ρ R ln R t R + ( 1 ρ R ) ϕ y ln y t y + ϕ π π t π ,

where ϕ y > 0 and ϕ π > 1 are policy coefficients when output and inflation deviate from the associated steady-state levels.

In the symmetric equilibrium, the final output (GDP) can be expressed as follows:

y t = 0 1 y j , t d j = n t x t .

By analogy, the market-clearing condition of capital is K t = n t k t . Accordingly, the aggregate resource constraint is given by

( 1 D t ) y t = c t + i t + C t ,

where D t = ψ p 2 π t π 1 2 is the output loss due to price stickiness, and C t = κ v t is the total vacancy posting cost.[10]

3 Labor Income Share and Productivity Shock

In this section, we calibrate our model to match the US economy, and perform a quantitative analysis to investigate the LIS dynamics in response to an unexpected Hicks-neutral productivity shock. We log-linearize the equilibrium conditions around the non-stochastic steady state and delicately examine the impulse response functions to the productivity/technology shock.

3.1 Calibration

In our model, a period corresponds to one quarter of a year. We set the subjective discount factor β = 0.99, implying that the annual real interest rate is around 4 percent. The risk aversion coefficient γ c is set to 2, in the neighborhood of most empirical estimates; see, for instance, Attanasio and Weber (1995) and Krause and Lubik (2007). We set the depreciation rate δ = 0.025, implying an annual depreciation rate of capital of 10 percent.

The matching efficiency γ m is calibrated so that the steady-state unemployment rate is 5.88 percent. Following Krause, Lopez-Salido, and Lubik (2008), we set the quarterly job separation rate as s = 0.05. Following Petrongolo and Pissarides (2001), we set the unemployment elasticity of matching ξ = 0.6. The period vacancy cost κ, which affects a firm’s willingness to open vacancies, is calibrated by targeting the steady-state vacancy-filling rate f v = 0.70, a valued adopted by den Haan, Ramey, and Watson (2000). We set the employed worker’s bargaining power η = 0.5, following den Haan et al. (2000). The unemployment benefit z is calibrated by targeting the replacement ratio of 0.4, which is widely adopted in the search and matching models.

As for structural parameters related to the household sector, we set γ h = 0.3026 so that the Frisch elasticity of labor supply is equal to 3.3. Chetty et al. (2011) suggest that for the business cycle models the reasonable range for this elasticity is between 2.61 and 4. We then choose the middle point value. The scale parameter of labor disutility Ψ is calibrated so that the steady-state working hours per worker amount to h = 0.3, which is commonly used in the RBC literature.

On the production side, we set the elasticity of factor substitution to σ = 0.5, which is in the neighborhood of recent empirical studies based on firm- and plant-level data.[11] We set the returns-to-scale parameter ϑ to 0.98, which implies that the profit share of a producing firm is 2 percent.[12] We calibrate the steady-state technology level A = 0.3305 so that the steady-state capital demand is k = 1 for each producing firm, associated with the capital rental rate of r k = 3.5%. Through the arbitrage condition, this implies a reasonable net real interest rate of r = 1.01% in the steady state. We assume that ϵ = 11; that is, a pricing firm’s steady-state (net) markup is 10 percent.

It is well known that the pricing schemes of Rotemberg (1982) and Calvo (1983) are observationally equivalent up to the first-order approximation. Utilizing this equivalent relationship, we set the price-adjustment-cost parameter ψ p = 60, which implies that two-thirds of pricing firms cannot reset their prices in the sense of Calvo pricing.[13] Moreover, we assume that the wage rigidity parameter ψ w = 0.6. Following Faia (2008), we set ϕ π = 1.5 and ϕ y = 0.125 in the nominal interest rate rule, with a normalized steady-state gross inflation of π = 1. Finally, for the sake of quantitative comparison, the persistence and volatility parameters (ρ A = 0.93 and σ A = 0.0064) are obtained from the structural estimation of Ríos-Rull and Santaeulàlia-Llopis (2010). Choosing exactly the same parameter values allows us to foster a quantitative comparison between the empirical and theoretical impulse responses. Table 1 summarizes our calibration.

Table 1:

Parameter values of the baseline model.

Parameter Description Value Source/target
β Subjective discount factor 0.99 Data
γ c Risk aversion coefficient 2 Krause and Lubik (2007)
γ h Labor supply parameter 2 Christoffel and Kuester (2008)
δ Depreciation rate 0.025 10 percent of annual depreciation
ξ Unempl. elasticity of matching 0.6 Petrongolo and Pissarides (2001)
η Bargaining power of a worker 0.5 den Haan et al. (2000)
s Separation rate 0.05 Krause et al. (2008)
σ Elasticity of substitution 0.5 See text
ψ w Sticky wage parameter 0.6 See text
ψ p Price adj. cost parameter 60 See text
ϵ Price elas. of int. goods 11 Christoffel and Kuester (2008)
ϑ Returns-to-scale parameter 0.98 Assumption for the baseline model
ϕ y Policy parameter: output 0.125 Faia (2008)
ϕ π Policy parameter: inflation 1.5 Faia (2008)
γ m Matching efficiency 0.7586 Unemployment rate: u = 0.0588
z Unemployment benefit 0.0426 Replacement ratio: z/wh = 0.40
α Distribution parameter on capital 0.5236 Historical average. labor share = 0.67
Ψ Labor disutility parameter 14.0673 Hours per worker: h = 0.3
κ Period vacancy cost 0.0336 Vacancy filling rate: f v = 0.7
A Steady state technology level 0.3305 Capital demand: k = 1
ρ A AR(1) parameter: technology 0.93 Ríos-Rull and Santaeulàlia-Llopis (2010)
σ A Innovation std. dev.: technology 0.0064 Ríos-Rull and Santaeulàlia-Llopis (2010)

3.2 Effects on the Labor Income Share

Technology shocks affect the LIS via two channels: the output elasticity of labor Φ t (the output-elasticity channel) and the price-cost markup μ t (the markup channel), as shown in (14). A positive technology shock raises both the marginal products of labor and capital for intermediate-good producing firms. Figure 2 shows that higher factor productivity makes opening vacancies more attractive, leading new firms to open job vacancies v t . Meanwhile, labor increases at both the intensive margin (hours per worker h t ) and extensive margin (employment n t ) (see the job creation condition (11)). Thus, the aggregate output y t increases and the unemployment rate u t decreases.

Figure 2: 
Impulse responses of a positive technology shock.
Figure 2:

Impulse responses of a positive technology shock.

Focusing on the impact effect, although working hours per worker and the number of employed workers (and hence the number of firms) increase, capital k t is unchanged on impact (since capital is predetermined). The time lag in adjusting capital causes the capital–labor ratio k t / h t to jump downward on impact. Since capital and labor are complementary (σ = 0.5), a lower capital–labor ratio decreases the output elasticity of labor Φ t (the output elasticity channel is shown in (13)), leading to a negative effect on LIS, Sl,t.

Regarding the markup channel, a positive technology shock leads the intermediate-good firms to increase their supply to pricing firms, which decreases the real marginal cost for pricing firms φ t . By contrast, with the labor-capital complementarity, the labor upward jump raises the rental rate of capital rk,t because the marginal product of capital increases with labor hours (the technological complementarity). A higher rental rate substantially increases the producing firm’s cost, which exerts upward pressure on the real marginal cost for pricing firms. Given these two conflicting effects, Figure 1 shows that the real marginal cost of pricing firms φ slightly increases in response to the technology shock. Because a pricing firm’s markup is the inverse of its real marginal cost, on impact the markup μ t decreases slightly. As a result of a small effect on the markup channel, the output elasticity channel dominates, leading to the counter-cyclicality of the LIS on impact.

Figure 2 further shows that, after the upward jump, the increment of labor hours gradually diminishes in transition. By contrast, capital increases and exhibits a hump-shaped response to the positive technology shock. The hump-shaped response of capital translates to a similar pattern in the capital–labor ratio and the output elasticity of labor, resulting in the LIS overshooting.

To be specific, after the impact, capital starts to increase. An increase in capital, on the one hand, lowers the rental rate rk,t (due to the diminishing returns to capital), and on the other hand, raises the wage rate w t (due to capital–labor complementarity). As a result, the relative factor price w t /rk,t increases in transition. In the presence of some degree of wage rigidity, the wage rate needs time to reach its maximizing level, and afterwards it gradually decreases because of the diminishing returns to labor. Thus, in transition the relative factor price increases first and then decreases, leading the capital–labor ratio to exhibit a hump-shaped response, as shown in (10). Under the CES production with factor complementarity (0 < σ < 1), this hump-shaped response translates into a similar pattern in the output elasticity of labor Φ t , as shown in (13). The output elasticity channel thus leads the LIS to overshoot its initial level. In the later periods of transition, the capital–labor ratio decreases, weakening the output elasticity channel, and the real marginal cost decreases, amplifying the markup channel. Therefore, the LIS eventually declines.

In our model, the asymmetric adjustment speeds of capital and labor generate the LIS dynamics in both the counter-cyclicality and overshooting. On impact, the adjustment speed of capital is slow so that the capital–labor ratio decreases. With the capital–labor complementarity, the LIS exhibits a counter-cyclicality. In transition, the adjustment speed of capital increases, and the increasing capital–labor ratio leads to the LIS overshooting. Since the positive technology shock eventually reduces the real marginal cost of firms, labor’s share declines in the longer run via the markup channel. The adjustment asymmetry between capital and labor may depend on the labor supply elasticity and the capital adjustment cost. It is intuitive to infer that the adjustment asymmetry between capital and labor is amplified (attenuated) by a higher elasticity of labor supply (a higher capital adjustment cost), resulting in more (less) responsive LIS dynamics.[14]

In a DMP search model with fully flexible wages and prices, Choi and Ríos-Rull (2009) also examine the LIS dynamics by using a non-unit elasticity of substitution between labor and capital. They persuasively argue the importance of labor-capital complementarity, but the magnitude of the LIS overshooting is very limited in their model. The empirical impulse response function shows that the LIS overshoots its initial level in the fifth quarter after the technology shock, and the overshooting is about 0.2% at the peak around the 18th quarter. In the Choi and Ríos-Rull (2009) model, the LIS overshooting is merely 0.02% relative to the initial level. By contrast, in our model, the capital–labor complementarity interacts with the wage/price rigidity. This interaction enables us to generate a more responsive LIS overshooting and better matches the empirical impulse responses of the LIS. Our calibration results show that the LIS overshoots its initial level at about the sixth or seventh quarter after the shock, and the magnitude of the overshooting is around 0.17% (the peak is also in the 18th quarter), which is also close to the data.

Furthermore, Table 2 compares our calibration results with the second moment and correlation of the business cycle statistics. The current empirical evidence indicates that the LIS is counter-cyclical in relation to output. In the US, the estimates of the correlation coefficient between the LIS and output range between −0.13 (estimated by Choi and Ríos-Rull 2009) and −0.34 (estimated by Koh and Santaeulàlia-Llopis 2017). In our model, the LIS-output correlation is −0.18, which is located well within the range of existing estimates. In focusing on the LIS variance, the estimated variance of the LIS is between 0.44 (estimated by Choi and Ríos-Rull 2009) and 0.55 (estimated by Koh and Santaeulàlia-Llopis 2017). In our baseline model, the variance of the LIS is 0.67, which is slightly higher than the empirically estimated value. The variance can be reduced to 0.49 with a lower labor supply elasticity of 1.92 (a reasonable value in the RBC literature), relative to the baseline elasticity of 3.3. Note that Table 2 shows that the negative correlation between the LIS and output cannot be produced without the rigidity in wages and prices.

Table 2:

Cyclicality and variance of labor income shares.

corr (y, S L ) var(S L )
Empirical data (0.34, −0.13) (0.436, 0.55)
Baseline −0.177 0.675
CD production function (σ = 1) −0.986 0.038
Flexible wage (ψ w = 0) 0.140 0.337
Flexible price (ψ p = 0) 0.101 1.171

4 Discussions

There are four novel features in the NK model with labor frictions: (i) the capital–labor complementarity, (ii) the wage rigidity, (iii) price rigidity via the endogenous markup, and (iv) the demand-side monetary policy, all of which affect the LIS dynamics. In what follows, we isolate the first three components one by one to sharpen their roles. Moreover, we perform a sensitivity analysis to examine how the government’s demand-side monetary policy interacts with the supply-side technology shock.

4.1 CD Production Function

To shed light on the role of the capital–labor complementarity, we reduce the CES production function to a CD one by setting the elasticity of substitution between capital and labor as σ = 1. Figure 3 shows that, under a CD production function, the counter-cyclicality of the LIS on impact becomes less pronounced, and the overshooting vanishes. This case vividly conveys the viewpoint of Choi and Ríos-Rull (2009) in the sense that the conventional DMP model may explain the counter-cyclicality of the LIS in response to a technology shock, but cannot address the overshooting.

Figure 3: 
CES production function (σ = 0.5) versus CD production function (σ = 1).
Figure 3:

CES production function (σ = 0.5) versus CD production function (σ = 1).

In the presence of a CD production function, the output elasticity of labor is a constant as shown in (13), and therefore the output elasticity effect is absent. As for the markup effect, the CD production function implies a lower degree of technological complementarity between capital and labor, relative to the CES production function. Due to a weaker technological complementarity, the impact of an increase in labor hours has a smaller effect on the rental rate.[15] It turns out that the pricing firm’s real marginal cost decreases and its markup increases in response to the positive technology shock. Because the markup becomes pro-cyclical, the LIS always exhibits a counter-cyclicality in transition. As a result, a CD production function eliminates the possibility of the LIS overshooting.

This experiment also implies that higher capital–labor complementarity reinforces the output elasticity channel, and hence increases the magnitude of overshooting to a higher level. Such a case becomes more important as the Introduction points out that recent empirical studies have supported an estimated elasticity of substitution between capital and labor significantly below unity.

4.2 Flexible Wages

Next, we shut off the wage rigidity by setting the degree of wage rigidity ψ w = 0. Figure 4 shows that if wages are fully flexible, the LIS becomes less responsive in both the counter-cyclicality and the overshooting. For instance, the magnitude of the LIS overshooting reduces to 0.11% relative to the initial level, around a half of the estimated magnitude. This experiment reveals that, with sticky wages, the LIS dynamics generated from our NK model can better match the empirical impulse responses.

Figure 4: 
Rigid wages (ψ
w
 = 0.6) versus flexible wages (ψ
w
 = 0).
Figure 4:

Rigid wages (ψ w = 0.6) versus flexible wages (ψ w = 0).

If wages are sticky, the timing of the increase in wages is postponed. Thus, on impact and at the beginning of the transition, wages increase less and labor hours increase more, compared to the flexible wage case. The remarkable increase in labor hours causes the rise in the rental rate to be more pronounced at the beginning of the transition. Because the adjustment speeds of capital and labor become more asymmetric, with a greater downward jump, the capital–labor ratio is lower at the beginning of the transition, but it jumps higher in the later periods of the transition. Therefore, through the output elasticity channel, the LIS jumps downwards more significantly and that the overshooting is more pronounced.

As for the markup channel, there are opposite effects in the sticky and flexible wage cases. As noted above, if wages are sticky, labor hours are more responsive to a technology shock, and the increase in the rental rate is more pronounced. Since producing firms demand more labor hours and face higher capital rental rates, the real marginal cost increases, leading to a decrease in the markup. By contrast, if wages are flexible, producing firms increase their labor less and face lower capital rental rates. As a result, the real marginal cost of firms decreases, rather than increases, raising their markups. Therefore, the LIS overshooting turns out to become less pronounced as wages are fully flexible. By contrast, because wage rigidity depresses the markup channel, the LIS overshooting is substantial.

In the absence of capital–labor complementarity, Colciago and Rossi (2015) and Reicher (2016) find that wage rigidity is not crucial in governing the LIS overshooting. Our result contradicts those of Colciago and Rossi (2015) and Reicher (2016). This experiment tells us that introducing a real wage rigidity into the DMP framework amplifies the channel of the output elasticity of labor, making the LIS overshooting more pronounced. With wage rigidity, our model can produce a better matching of the amplitude of the LIS overshooting observed in the data even in the presence of pro-cyclical markups.

4.3 Flexible Prices

Price rigidity endogenizes firms’ markups in the model. We thus isolate the markup effect by shutting off price rigidity (by setting ψ p = 0). When prices are fully flexible, markups become fixed, and therefore, the markup channel is shut down. In the case without the markup channel, Figure 5 shows that the LIS overshooting in transition becomes more significant. As noted in the baseline, price markups are pro-cyclical in transition, which weakens the channel of the output elasticity of labor. Therefore, the LIS overshooting in transition becomes more pronounced when we shut off the markup channel.

Figure 5: 
Rigid prices (ψ
p
 = 60) versus flexible prices (ψ
p
 = 0).
Figure 5:

Rigid prices (ψ p = 60) versus flexible prices (ψ p = 0).

This case provides a counterexample to the finding of Colciago and Rossi (2015). In the absence of factor complementarity, they argue that the counter-cyclicality of the price markup, instead of wage rigidity, plays an important role in generating a more responsive LIS overshooting. By contrast, in our model wage rigidity amplifies the overshooting of the LIS, but price rigidity attenuates it. Even though the markup channel is absent, the interaction between wage rigidity and the capital–labor complementarity can still command the dynamics of the LIS, leading to a better matching of the amplitude of overshooting.

4.4 Demand-Side Monetary Policy

Since we adopt a New Keynesian framework, we can examine how the demand-side monetary policy interacts with the supply-side technology shock, and how the interaction governs the LIS dynamics. Figures 6 and 7 show that the LIS overshooting becomes more pronounced if the government has a more active inflation-targeting policy (increasing the inflation response parameter ϕ π from 1.5 to 2.5), but it becomes less pronounced if the government has a more active output-targeting policy (increasing the output response parameter ϕ y from 0.125 to 0.5).

Figure 6: 
Sensitivity analysis with respect to the policy parameter for inflation in the interest rate rule (ϕ
π
 = 1.5 and ϕ
π
 = 2.5).
Figure 6:

Sensitivity analysis with respect to the policy parameter for inflation in the interest rate rule (ϕ π = 1.5 and ϕ π = 2.5).

Figure 7: 
Sensitivity analysis with respect to the policy parameter for output in the interest rate rule (ϕ
y
 = 0.125 and ϕ
y
 = 0.5).
Figure 7:

Sensitivity analysis with respect to the policy parameter for output in the interest rate rule (ϕ y = 0.125 and ϕ y = 0.5).

The government’s inflation-targeting policy affects the LIS dynamics mainly through the markup channel. Intuitively, a more active inflation-targeting policy restrains the downward trend of inflation caused by a technological advance, making the aggregate output more responsive, as shown in Figure 6. In transition, this restraint on inflation further limits the downward trend in the trading price of intermediate goods. Thus, the real marginal cost of intermediate-good pricing firms φ t decreases less, and hence, its markup μ t = 1/φ t increases less as well. Because markups are not so pro-cyclical in transition, we can see from (14) that the LIS overshooting becomes more significant under a more active inflation-targeting policy.

By contrast, a more active output-targeting policy leads the LIS overshooting to become less responsive. Figure 7 shows that if the government stabilizes the output level more aggressively, the aggregate output increases less but the inflation rate decreases more. Because the stabilization effect of the demand-side policy restrains the supply-side output expansion, the output elasticity channel becomes weaker, while the markup channel becomes stronger. Both substantially reduce the overshooting magnitude of the LIS.

5 Concluding Remarks

In this paper, we examine the labor share dynamics by incorporating the capital–labor complementarity in a CES production function and wage/price rigidity in imperfect product and labor markets into a DSGE model with search and matching frictions. By highlighting the channels of the output elasticity and the price-cost markup, we spell out the mechanism behind the cyclical movements of the LIS, namely, counter-cyclicality on impact and overshooting in transition.

We show that wage rigidity interacts with the capital–labor complementarity, and this interaction produces a good matching of the amplitude of the LIS overshooting observed in the data. While price rigidity reduces the magnitude of LIS overshooting, it helps match empirically estimated negative correlations between the labor share and output. There is a disparity in the sense that the decline in the LIS is theoretically attributed to a greater-than-unity elasticity of substitution between capital and labor, but empirical studies show that the estimate of this elasticity could be less than one. Our model can reconcile such a disparity. With the rigidity in wages and prices, the negative correlation between the LIS and output can harmonize with the capital–labor complementarity conditional on a positive technology shock.

We also show that the LIS overshooting becomes more pronounced if the government’s interest rate rule is more responsive to the deviation in the inflation target, but it becomes less pronounced if the government’s interest rate rule is more responsive to the deviation in the output target. A more active inflation-targeting policy allows us to further improve the matching of the amplitude of the LIS overshooting observed in the data.


Corresponding author: Chun-Hung Kuo, Department of Economics, National Tsing Hua University. No. 101, Section 2, Kuang-Fu Road, Hsinchu 300, Taiwan, ROC, E-mail:

Award Identifier / Grant number: MOST 108-2410-H-007-101

Acknowledgements

We thank two anonymous referees, Arpad Abraham (Managing Editor), Hiroaki Miyamoto, Ching-Chong Lai, and Been-Lon Chen for their insightful comments on an earlier draft of this paper, whose inputs have led to a much improved paper. We are grateful for financial support provided by the Ministry of Science and Technology, Taiwan. Any remaining errors are, of course, our own responsibility.

References

Andolfatto, D. 1996. “Business Cycles and Labor-Market Search.” The American Economic Review 86: 112–32.Search in Google Scholar

Antràs, P. 2004. “Is the U.S. Aggregate Production Function Cobb-Douglas? New Estimates of the Elasticity of Substitution.” Contributions to Macroeconomics 4: 1–34. https://doi.org/10.2202/1534-6005.1161.Search in Google Scholar

Arpaia, A., E. Párez, and K. Pichelmann. 2009. “Understanding Labour Income Share Dynamics in Europe.” European Economy - Economic Papers 2008 - 2015 379.Search in Google Scholar

Attanasio, O. P., and G. Weber. 1995. “Is Consumption Growth Consistent with Intertemporal Optimization? Evidence from the Consumer Expenditure Survey.” Journal of Political Economy 103: 1121–57. https://doi.org/10.1086/601443.Search in Google Scholar

Benhabib, J., and R. E. Farmer. 1994. “Indeterminacy and Increasing Returns.” Journal of Economic Theory 63: 19–41. https://doi.org/10.1006/jeth.1994.1031.Search in Google Scholar

Bilbiie, F. O., F. Ghironi, and M. J. Melitz. 2012. “Endogenous Entry, Product Variety, and Business Cycles.” Journal of Political Economy 120: 304–45. https://doi.org/10.1086/665825.Search in Google Scholar

Blanchard, O., and J. Galí. 2010. “Labor Markets and Monetary Policy: A New Keynesian Model with Unemployment.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 2: 1–30. https://doi.org/10.1257/mac.2.2.1.Search in Google Scholar

Calvo, G. A. 1983. “Staggered Prices in a Utility-Maximizing Framework.” Journal of Monetary Economics 12: 383–98. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(83)90060-0.Search in Google Scholar

Chetty, R., A. Guren, D. Manoli, and A. Weber. 2011. “Are Micro and Macro Labor Supply Elasticities Consistent? A Review of Evidence on the Intensive and Extensive Margins.” The American Economic Review 101: 471–5. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.101.3.471.Search in Google Scholar

Chirinko, R. S., and D. Mallick. 2017. “The Substitution Elasticity, Factor Shares, and the Low-Frequency Panel Model.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 9: 225–53. https://doi.org/10.1257/mac.20140302.Search in Google Scholar

Chirinko, R. S., S. M. Fazzari, and A. P. Meyer. 2011. “A New Approach to Estimating Production Function Parameters: The Elusive Capital–Labor Substitution Elasticity.” Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 29: 587–94. https://doi.org/10.1198/jbes.2011.08119.Search in Google Scholar

Choi, S., and J. V. Ríos-Rull. 2009. “Understanding the Dynamics of Labor Share: The Role of Noncompetitive Factor Prices.” Annals of Economics and Statistics: 251–77. https://doi.org/10.2307/27917412.Search in Google Scholar

Choi, S., and J. V. Ríos-Rull. 2021. “Labour Share and Productivity Dynamics.” The Economic Journal 131: 2856–86. https://doi.org/10.1093/ej/ueaa137.Search in Google Scholar

Christoffel, K., and K. Kuester. 2008. “Resuscitating the Wage Channel in Models with Unemployment Fluctuations.” Journal of Monetary Economics 55: 865–87. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2008.03.009.Search in Google Scholar

Colciago, A., and L. Rossi. 2015. “Firm Dynamics, Endogenous Markups, and the Labor Share of Income.” Macroeconomic Dynamics 19: 1309–31. https://doi.org/10.1017/s1365100513000849.Search in Google Scholar

Den Haan, W. J., G. Ramey, and J. Watson. 2000. “Job Destruction and Propagation of Shocks.” The American Economic Review 90: 482–98. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.90.3.482.Search in Google Scholar

Drautzburg, T., J. Fernandez-Villaverde, and P. Guerron-Quintana. 2020. “Bargaining Shocks and Aggregate Fluctuations.” Working Papers 20-11. Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia.10.21799/frbp.wp.2020.11Search in Google Scholar

Faia, E. 2008. “Optimal Monetary Policy Rules with Labor Market Frictions.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 32: 1600–21. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jedc.2007.06.011.Search in Google Scholar

Gertler, M., and A. Trigari. 2009. “Unemployment Fluctuations with Staggered Nash Wage Bargaining.” Journal of Political Economy 117: 38–86. https://doi.org/10.1086/597302.Search in Google Scholar

Hall, R. E. 2005. “Employment Fluctuations with Equilibrium Wage Stickiness.” The American Economic Review 95: 50–65. https://doi.org/10.1257/0002828053828482.Search in Google Scholar

Karabarbounis, L., and B. Neiman. 2014. “The Global Decline of the Labor Share.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 129: 61–103. https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjt032.Search in Google Scholar

Koh, D., and R. Santaeulàlia-Llopis. 2017. “Countercyclical Elasticity of Substitution.” Working Papers 946. Barcelona Graduate School of Economics.Search in Google Scholar

Krause, M. U., and T. A. Lubik. 2007. “The (Ir)relevance of Real Wage Rigidity in the New Keynesian Model with Search Frictions.” Journal of Monetary Economics 54: 706–27. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2005.12.001.Search in Google Scholar

Krause, M. U., D. J. Lopez-Salido, and T. A. Lubik. 2008. “Inflation Dynamics with Search Frictions: A Structural Econometric Analysis.” Journal of Monetary Economics 55: 892–916. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2008.04.004.Search in Google Scholar

León-Ledesma, M. A., and M. Satchi. 2019. “Appropriate Technology and Balanced Growth.” The Review of Economic Studies 86: 807–35. https://doi.org/10.1093/restud/rdy002.Search in Google Scholar

León-Ledesma, M. A., P. McAdam, and A. Willman. 2010. “Identifying the Elasticity of Substitution with Biased Technical Change.” The American Economic Review 100: 1330–57. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.100.4.1330.Search in Google Scholar

León-Ledesma, M. A., P. McAdam, and A. Willman. 2015. “Production Technology Estimates and Balanced Growth.” Oxford Bulletin of Economics & Statistics 77: 40–65. https://doi.org/10.1111/obes.12049.Search in Google Scholar

Mangin, S., and P. Sedláček. 2018. “Unemployment and the Labor Share.” Journal of Monetary Economics 94: 41–59. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2017.10.001.Search in Google Scholar

Merz, M. 1995. “Search in the Labor Market and the Real Business Cycle.” Journal of Monetary Economics 36: 269–300. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(95)01216-8.Search in Google Scholar

Petrongolo, B., and C. A. Pissarides. 2001. “Looking into the Black Box: A Survey of the Matching Function.” Journal of Economic Literature 39: 390–431. https://doi.org/10.1257/jel.39.2.390.Search in Google Scholar

Pissarides, C. A. 1990. Equilibrium Unemployment Theory. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Search in Google Scholar

Raurich, X., H. Sala, and V. Sorolla. 2012. “Factor Shares, the Price Markup, and the Elasticity of Substitution between Capital and Labor.” Journal of Macroeconomics 34: 181–98. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmacro.2011.09.004.Search in Google Scholar

Raval, D. R. 2019. “The Micro Elasticity of Substitution and Non-neutral Technology.” The RAND Journal of Economics 50: 147–67. https://doi.org/10.1111/1756-2171.12265.Search in Google Scholar

Reicher, C. A. 2016. “Matching Labor’s Share in a Search and Matching Model.” Empirical Economics 50: 1229–54. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-015-0985-0.Search in Google Scholar

Ríos-Rull, J. V., and R. Santaeulàlia-Llopis. 2010. “Redistributive Shocks and Productivity Shocks.” Journal of Monetary Economics 57: 931–48. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2010.10.005.Search in Google Scholar

Rotemberg, J. J. 1982. “Sticky Prices in the United States.” Journal of Political Economy 90: 1187–211. https://doi.org/10.1086/261117.Search in Google Scholar

Shao, E., and P. Silos. 2013. “Entry Costs and Labor Market Dynamics.” European Economic Review 63: 243–55. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.euroecorev.2013.07.009.Search in Google Scholar

Shimer, R. 2005. “The Cyclical Behavior of Equilibrium Unemployment and Vacancies.” The American Economic Review 95: 25–49. https://doi.org/10.1257/0002828053828572.Search in Google Scholar

Smets, F., and R. Wouters. 2007. “Shocks and Frictions in US Business Cycles: A Bayesian DSGE Approach.” The American Economic Review 97: 586–606. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.97.3.586.Search in Google Scholar

Sunakawa, T. 2012. “Efficiency in a Search and Matching Model with Right-to-Manage Bargaining.” Economics Letters 117: 679–82. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2011.12.072.Search in Google Scholar

Thomas, C. 2008. “Search and Matching Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy.” Journal of Monetary Economics 55: 936–56. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2008.03.007.Search in Google Scholar

Trigari, A. 2006. “The Role of Search Frictions and Bargaining for Inflation Dynamics.” Working Papers 304. IGIER (Innocenzo Gasparini Institute for Economic Research), Bocconi University.10.2139/ssrn.886021Search in Google Scholar

Received: 2021-05-01
Revised: 2021-12-24
Accepted: 2022-03-04
Published Online: 2022-03-24

© 2022 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Downloaded on 5.5.2024 from https://www.degruyter.com/document/doi/10.1515/bejm-2021-0101/html
Scroll to top button