Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Price dynamics of Swedish pharmaceuticals

  • Published:
Quantitative Marketing and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper investigates price patterns of off-patent pharmaceuticals in Sweden. I show that price dynamics are dependent on the number of competitors in the market. The price patterns follow predictions from a model of dynamic price competition in which the demand for pharmaceuticals incorporates the known biases of consumers: habit persistence and brand preferences. Using the regulated market of Swedish pharmaceuticals, I show that price dynamics may help in identifying possible tacit collusion by manufacturers in markets where consumers experience behavioral frictions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Regulation of substitution to generics is dependent on the federal state, and prices are based on a free-market mechanism. In 2014 and 2015, the prices of several generic products increased in the US, although there were many producers of a single homogeneous product (Los Angeles Times, 2016), attracting the attention of antitrust regulators. The puzzle of many producers and increasing prices has been featured on Reinhardt’s health care blog (Reinhardt, 2016). The suspected price increases by all competitors led to an investigation by antitrust authorities in November 2016 (Bloomberg, 2016).

  2. The existence of switching costs has been documented in various empirical studies, including (Calem & Mester, 1995; Dubé et al., 2010; Keane, 1997; Shcherbakov, 2016; Shum, 2004; Shy, 2002), and (Viard, 2007). Relevance in the pharmaceutical market is documented in Crawford and Shum (2005) and Hollis (2002), and (Feng, 2017).

  3. Note also the existence of similar models in monopolistic competition, i.e., Conlisk et al. (1984) and Sobel (1984), or Villas-Boas (2006). The literature shows that price cycles are even possible for monopolists under some conditions (i.e., durable goods). Another stream of literature considers similar models where consumers are forward looking, e.g., Dutta et al. (2007).

  4. The exact co-payment functions before and after a reform in 2012 are described in Online Appendix ??. Costs for pharmaceuticals that are not in the benefit scheme are not covered, and their prices are therefore less regulated. Prescription-free (i.e., over-the-counter) medicines that are not solely sold in pharmacies and other traded pharmacy goods are generally not subsidized. Pharmaceuticals prescribed for children under 18 years old, insulin, pharmaceuticals that combat communicable diseases, and pharmaceuticals for persons who lack an understanding of their own illness are fully subsidized, and those patients do not have any expenses.

  5. In case the original prescription drug is chosen, the out-of-pocket expense equals the price difference between the cheapest product and the prescribed product. If a patient wants to purchase a third pharmaceutical that is neither prescribed nor the product of the month, the patient pays the entire price out of pocket. Note that empirically only out-of-pocket expenses equal to the price differences are observable.

  6. A price ceiling exists if a branded drug is under generic competition for at least four months and the price of a drug has decreased by 70% of the original branded product’s price 12 months prior to patent expiration. If no price ceiling exists, the most expensive product of the month will serve as the price ceiling. If an original product has insufficient generic competition, prices may also be reduced by 7.5% if marketing approval was received at least 15 years before (TLV, 2016c).

  7. The exact function from purchasing to retail prices is described in Online Appendix ??. The function had a slight change in 2016 (TLV, 2016a). Pharmacies were privatized in 2009. Two thirds of the pharmacies were privatized, and the remaining third remain under public control.

  8. Additionally, a pharmacy can sell the remainder of the previous product of the month during the first two weeks of a new month. After these two weeks, pharmacies can sell the products for the pharmacy-purchasing price without profit. Therefore, the pharmacy has no incentive to overstock a product of the month.

  9. Most prominent are examples in the gasoline market (see for example (Byrne et al., 2015; Byrne and De Roos, 2019; Castanias & Johnson, 1993; Lewis, 2012; Noel, 2007a; 2007b; 2008; Wang, 2009; Zimmerman et al., 2013)).

  10. Note that pharmacies are a passive actor in the market. They receive a fixed retail margin. Therefore I do not model pharmacies as agents but instead model manufacturers as facing consumers directly.

  11. Let − j = N ∖{j}.

  12. The assumption is in line with empirical observations within the data. Note first that the difference between the cheapest and most expensive product is often not high due to the tight setting of the upper bound R. The average maximal price difference between the cheapest product and most expensive product across all substitution groups is 112.2 SEK (approx. 11.2 USD). After controlling for whether a product is the cheapest product within a substitution group, a price decrease of 100 SEK (approx. 10 USD) is associated with a market share increase of only 1 percentage point; see the empirical part of this paper in Section 6.

  13. Proof in Lemma 2; see Online Appendix C.

  14. See Online Appendix A for details.

  15. Note that pharmacies are allowed to sell the remaining stock of previously purchased products in the first two weeks of the next month for the same price as the last month. I exclude those observations as they may lead to an overestimation of habit persistence. The presented estimate can be interpreted as a lower bound of habit persistence.

  16. One potential explanation is that users of antiepileptics are used to switch drugs within a substitution group frequently. Thus they are likely to switch a product if a new, cheaper product becomes available.

  17. Note that the same price setting is defined as the situation in which at least two firms set the same price over three subsequent months.

  18. Note that \(\hat {\beta }_{1c}\) is also negative. I therefore transform the variable by adding the absolute minimum of \(\hat {\beta }_{1c}\) across substances and 0.001 to \(\hat {\beta }_{1c}\) before taking the logarithm.

  19. The ATC code is ordered according to five levels. The first level describes the main anatomical group, the second level the main therapeutic group, the third level the pharmacological subgroup, the fourth level the chemical subgroup, and the fifth level the exact chemical substance. For this analysis, I use up the ATC code up to the fifth level.

  20. Using prices to detect collusion is common in procurement auctions (Chassang et al., 2022; Ishii, 2014; Kawai & Nakabayashi, 2022; Kawai et al., 2022). Recent related research focuses on algorithmic pricing and collusion (Calvano et al., 2020).

References

  • Amelio, A., & Biancini, S. (2010). Alternating monopoly and tacit collusion. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 58, 402–423.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, E.T. (1995). Essays on pricing and advertising. Dissertation. Massachusetts Institute of Technology.

  • Anderson, E.T., & Kumar, N. (2007). Price competition with repeat, loyal buyers. Quantitative Marketing and Economics, 5, 333–359.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, E.T., Kumar, N., & Rajiv, S. (2004). A comment on: revisiting dynamic duopoly with consumer switching costs. Journal of Economic Theory, 116, 177–186.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andersson, K., Sonesson, C., Petzold, M., Carlsten, A., & Lönnroth, K (2005). What are the obstacles to generic substitution? An assessment of the behaviour of prescribers, patients and pharmacies during the first year of generic substitution in Sweden. Pharmacoepidemiology and Drug Safety, 14, 341–348.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arie, G., & Grieco, P.L.E. (2014). Who pays for switching costs? Quantitative Marketing and Economics, 12, 379–419.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beggs, A., & Klemperer, P. (1992). Multi-period competition with switching costs. Econometrica, 60, 651–666.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergman, M., Granlund, D., & Rudholm, N. (2012). Apoteksmarknadens omreglering - effekter på följsamhet, priser och kostnader per dygnsdos. Tillvaextanalys, Workingpaper 19.

  • Bergman, M A, Granlund, D., & Rudholm, N. (2016). Reforming the Swedish pharmaceuticals market: Consequences for costs per defined daily dose. International Journal of Health Economics and Management, 16(3), 201–214.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergman, M.A., Granlund, D., & Rudholm, N. (2017). Squeezing the last drop out of your suppliers: An empirical study of market-based purchasing policies for generic pharmaceuticals. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 79(6), 969–996.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloomberg. (2016). U.S. charges in generic-drug probe to be filed by year-end. https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2016-11-03/u-s-charges-in-generic-drug-probe-said-to-be-filed-by-year-end Accessed: 2017-02-23.

  • Bronnenberg, B.J., Dubé, J.-P., Gentzkow, M., & Shapiro, J.M. (2015). Do pharmacists buy Bayer? Informed shoppers and the brand premium. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 130, 1669–1726.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Byrne, D.P., & De Roos, N. (2019). Learning to coordinate: A study in retail gasoline. American Economic Review, 109(2), 591–619.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Byrne, D.P., Leslie, G.W., & Ware, R. (2015). How do consumers respond to gasoline price cycles? The Energy Journal 36(1).

  • Cabral, L. (2016). Dynamic pricing in customer markets with switching costs. Review of Economic Dynamics, 20, 43–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calem, P.S., & Mester, L.J. (1995). Consumer behavior and the stickiness of credit-card interest rates. The American Economic Review, 85(5), 1327–1336.

    Google Scholar 

  • Calvano, E., Calzolari, G., Denicolo, V., & Pastorello, S. (2020). Artificial intelligence, algorithmic pricing, and collusion. American Economic Review, 110(10), 3267–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Castanias, R., & Johnson, H. (1993). Gas wars: Retail gasoline price fluctuations. The Review of Economics and Statistics 171–174.

  • Chassang, S., Kawai, K., Nakabayashi, J., & Ortner, J. (2022). Robust screens for noncompetitive bidding in procurement auctions. Econometrica, 90 (1), 315–346.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, R., Fabiilli, C A, Lasio, L., & et al. (2021). Collusion in the us generic drug industry.

  • Clark, R., & Houde, J.-F. (2013). Collusion with asymmetric retailers: Evidence from a gasoline price-fixing case. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 5(3), 97–123.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cletus, J. (2016). Investigation of bid collusion within the Swedish generic drugs market. Master Thesis. University of Gothenburg. https://gupea.ub.gu.se/handle/2077/46761 Accessed 23 Feb 2017.

  • Conlisk, J., Gerstner, E., & Sobel, J. (1984). Cyclic pricing by a durable goods monopolist. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 99, 489–505.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crawford, G.S., & Shum, M. (2005). Uncertainty and learning in pharmaceutical demand. Econometrica, 73, 1137–1173.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cuddy, E. (2020). Competition and collusion in the generic drug market. Mimeo.

  • Daughety, A F, & Forsythe, R. (1988). Complete information outcomes without common knowledge. In Proceedings of the 2nd conference on Theoretical aspects of reasoning about knowledge (pp. 195–209). Morgan Kaufmann Publishers Inc.

  • Dubé, J.-P., Hitsch, G.J., & Rossi, P.E. (2009). Do switching costs make markets less competitive? Journal of Marketing Research, 46, 435–445.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dubé, J.-P., Hitsch, G.J., & Rossi, P.E. (2010). State dependence and alternative explanations for consumer inertia. RAND Journal of Economics, 41, 417–445.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dubois, P., & Lasio, L. (2018). Identifying industry margins with price constraints: Structural estimation on pharmaceuticals. American Economic Review, 108(12), 3685–3724.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dubois, P., & Sæthre, M. (2020). On the effect of parallel trade on manufacturers’ and retailers’ profits in the pharmaceutical sector. Econometrica, 88(6), 2503–2545.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dutta, P., Matros, A., & Weibull, J.W. (2007). Long-run price competition. RAND Journal of Economics, 38, 291–313.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eckert, A. (2002). Retail price cycles and response asymmetry. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d’économique, 35 (1), 52–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Einav, L., Finkelstein, A., & Williams, H. (2016). Paying on the margin for medical care: Evidence from breast cancer treatments. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 8(1), 52–79.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fabra, N., & García, A (2015). Market structure and the competitive effects of switching costs. Economics Letters, 126, 150–155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farrell, J., & Klemperer, P. (2007). Coordination and lock-in: Competition with switching costs and network effects. Handbook of industrial organization, 3, 1967–2072.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feng, J. (2017). History-dependent demand and intermediaries: Explaining prescription drug pricing dynamics. Unpublished.

  • Frank, R. G., & Salkever, D. S.(1991) Pricing, patent loss and the market for pharmaceuticals.

  • Frank, R. G., & Salkever, D. S.(1997).Generic entry and the pricing of pharmaceuticals. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy6, 75–90.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grabowski, H. G.(1996). Longer patents for increased genetic competition: The Waxman-Hatch Actafteronedecade. Pharmaco Economics 10.

  • Granlund, D. (2010). Price and welfare effects of a pharmaceutical substitution reform. Journal of Health Economics29, 856–865.

    Google Scholar 

  • Granlund, D. (2021). A new approach to estimating state dependence in consumers’ brand choices applied to 762 pharmaceutical markets. The Journal of Industrial Economics69(2), 443–483.

    Google Scholar 

  • Granlund, D., & Bergman, M. A.(2018). Price competition in pharmaceuticals–evidence from 1303 Swedish markets. Journal of Health Economics61, 1–12.

    Google Scholar 

  • Granlund, D., & Rudholm, N. (2008). Consumer loyalty in the Swedish pharmaceutical market. Umeå Economic Studies 742.

  • Hollis, A. (2002). The importance of being first: Evidence from Canadian generic pharmaceuticals. Health Economics11,723–734.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holt, T., Igami, M., & Scheidegger, S. (2021). Detecting Edge worth cycles. arXiv:2111.03434.

  • Ishii, R. (2014). Bid roundness under collusion in Japanese procure mentauctions. Review of Industrial Organization, 44(3), 241–254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Janssen, A. (2019). Switching costs, brand premia and behavioral pricing in the pharmaceutical market. Unpublished.

  • Kawai, K., & Nakabayashi, J. (2022). Detecting large-scale collusion in procurementauctions. Journal of Political Economy.

  • Kawai, K., Nakabayashi, J., Ortner, J. M., & Chassang, S. (2022). Using bid rotation and in cumbency to detect collusion: A regression discontinuity approach. Review of Economic Studies.

  • Keane, M. P. (1997). Modeling hetero geneity and state dependence in consumer choice behavior. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 15, 310–327.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klemperer, P. (1987). The competitiveness of markets with switching costs. RAND Journal of Economics, 138–150.

  • Klemperer, P. (1987). Markets with consumer switching costs. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 102, 375–394.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewis, M. S. (2012). Price leadership and coordination in retail gasoline markets with price cycles. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 30(4), 342–351.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Los Angeles Times. (2016). Here’s why drug prices rise even when there’s plenty of competition. http://www.latimes.com/business/la-fi-mylan-price-hikes-20160830-snap-story.html. Accessed 23 Feb 2017.

  • MacKay, A., & Remer, M. (2021). Consumer inertia and market power. Available at SSRN: 3380390.

  • Maskin, E., & Tirole, J. (2001). Markov perfect equilibrium: I observable actions. Journal of Economic Theory, 100, 191–219.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Noel, M. D. (2007). Edge worth price cycles, cost-based pricing, and sticky pricing in retail gasoline markets. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 89, 324–334.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Noel, M. D. (2007). Edge worth price cycles: Evidence from the Toronto retail gasoline market. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 55, 69–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Noel, M. D. (2008). Edge worth price cycles and focal prices: Computational dynamic Markov equilibria. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, 17(2), 345–377.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nosal, K. (2012). Estimating switching costs for Medicare Advantage plans. Unpublished manuscript, University of Mannheim.

  • Padilla, A. J. (1995). Revisiting dynamic duo poly with consumer switching costs. Journal of Economic Theory, 67, 520–530.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plum Hauschultz, F., & Munk-Nielsen, A. (2017). Priscyklerimarkedet for receptpligtig medicin efterpatentudlob. Konkurrence-og Forbrugerstyrelsen: Velfungerende markeder, 1–8.

  • Regan, T. L. (2008). Generic entry, price competition, and market segmentation in the prescription drug market. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 26, 930–948.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reinhardt, U. (2016). On the wondrous U.S. market for prescription drugs. The Health Care Blog, http://thehealthcareblog.com/blog/2016/09/04/on-the-wondrous-u-s-market-for-prescription-drugs/. . Accessed 23 Feb 2017.

  • Rhodes, A. (2014). Re-examining the effects of switching costs. Economic Theory, 57, 161–194.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ruiz-Aliseda, F. (2016). When do switching costs make markets more or less competitive?. International Journal of Industrial Organization47, 121–151.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shcherbakov, O. (2016). Measuring consumer switching costs in the television industry. RAND Journal of Economics, 47, 366–393.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shin, S., Misra, S., & Horsky, D. (2012). Disentangling preferences and learning in brand choice models. Marketing Science, 31(1), 115–137.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shum, M. (2004). Does advertising over come brand loyalty? Evidence from the breakfast-cereals market. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, 13, 241–272.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shy, O. (2002). A quick-and-easy method for estimating switching costs. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 20, 71–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sobel, J. (1984). The timing of sales. The Review of Economic Studies, 51, 353–368.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sorensen, A. T. (2000). Equilibrium price dispersion in retail markets for prescription drugs. Journal of Political Economy, 108(4), 833–850.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Starc, A., & Wollmann, T. G. (2022). Does entry remedy collusion? Evidence from the generic prescription drug cartel. National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • TLV. (2016). Apotekens marginaler. http://www.tlv.se/apotek/Apotekens-marginaler/. . Accessed 23 Feb 2017.

  • TLV.  (2016). Period ensvaror. http://www.tlv.se/apotek/utbyte-av-lakemedel-pa-apotek/periodens-varor/. Accessed 23 Feb 2017.

  • TLV. (2016). Takpriser. http://www.tlv.se/lakemedel/takpriser/.. Accessed 23 Feb 2017.

  • Viard, V. B. (2007). Do switching costs make markets more or less competitive? The case of 800-number portability. RAND Journal of Economics, 38, 146–163.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Villas-Boas, J. M. (2006). Dynamic competition with experience goods. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, 15, 37–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang, Z. (2009). (Mixed) strategy in oligopoly pricing: Evidence from gasoline price cycles before and under a timing  regulation. Journal of Political Economy, 117(6), 987–1030.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weiergraeber, S. (2021). Network effects and switching costs in the US wireless industry. International Economic Review.

  • Yeo, J., & Miller, D. P. (2018). Estimating switching costs with market share data: An application to Medicare Part D. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 61, 459–501.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zimmerman, P. R., Yun, J. M., & Taylor, C. T. (2013). Edge worth price cycles in gasoline: Evidence from the United States. Review of Industrial Organization, 42(3), 297–320.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Funding

Financial support from the Jan Wallander and Tom Hedelius Foundation is gratefully acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Aljoscha Janssen.

Additional information

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

I thank Richard Friberg and Albin Erlansson for detailed feedback. I also thank Liran Einav, Raffaele Fiocco, Magnus Johannesson, Brad Larsen, Erik Lindqvist, Dennis Rickert, Michelle Sovinsky, Giancarlo Spagnolo, Mark Voorneveld, and Jörgen Weibull as well as seminar participants at Stanford University, the Stockholm School of Economics, the annual conference of the EARIE 2018 in Athens, the annual conference of the EEA 2018 in Cologne, the annual conference of the IIOC 2018 in Indianapolis, the Spring Meeting of Young Economists at the University of the Balearic Islands, the annual conference of the Verein fuer Socialpolitik 2018 in Freiburg, the ENTER Jamboree 2018 at the Toulouse School of Economics, the SUDSWEC conference, the IO student workshop at the Toulouse School of Economics, the Swedish Workshop on Competition Economics and Public Procurement, and the Ruhr Graduate School of Economics doctoral conference for helpful comments.

Supplementary Information

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

ESM 1

Supplementary file1 (PDF 577 KB)

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Janssen, A. Price dynamics of Swedish pharmaceuticals. Quant Mark Econ 20, 313–351 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11129-022-09257-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11129-022-09257-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation