1 Introduction

The ongoing COVID-19 pandemic has caused a global health crisis resulting in more than 180 million reported cases and 3.800.000 casualties, as of the end of June 2021. Policymakers in many countries have responded to the pandemic by introducing a large variety of containment measures (see Cheng et al. 2020; Haug et al. 2020). Many of these measures have substantial implications for economic activity confronting policymakers with a trade-off between a rapid containment of the pandemic and the prevention of severe economic disruptions. Finding a balanced policy mix to resolve this trade-off is a major political challenge, for which it is crucial to develop a thorough understanding of the joint epidemic (number of infected, mortality) and economic (GDP loss, sectoral unemployment) effects of different measures (Murray 2020). Whereas well-established epidemiological models can be employed to address the first of these issues (e.g., Kissler et al. 2020; Giordano et al. 2020; Ferretti et al. 2020; Britton et al. 2020), rigorous approaches for studying both dynamics simultaneously are still sparse. Considering these two aspects in an integrated framework is important not only because many containment measures have direct economic effects, but also because several main infection channels are directly related to economic activity (Chang et al. 2021).

The growing economic literature investigating the COVID-19 pandemic on a theoretical level mainly builds upon the standard equation-based SIR model to model the infectious disease ( Kermack and McKendrick 1927; Hethcote 2000) and introduces some links to economic activity. Measures taken to contain the pandemic thereby typically reduce production potential or consumption and hence induce an economic shock. The interplay between containment measures and economic costs is then studied as an optimization problem from a social planner’s point of view (e.g., Alvarez et al. 2020; Miclo et al. 2020; Acemoglu et al. 2020), or embedded in a simple macroeconomic framework, where agents individually optimize their decisions (e.g., Eichenbaum et al. 2021; Krueger et al. 2020; Jones et al. 2020). Such abstract models rely on deterministic representations of the virus dynamics and do not capture the local and complex social interactions associated with economic activities (Epstein 2009), which play an important role in the propagation of the coronavirus (see, e.g., Wu et al. 2020; Prather et al. 2020). Hence, these models neither take the interplay between economic structure (e.g., size and sectoral distribution of firms) and the transmission dynamics into account nor capture the stochastic variation of economic and epidemic dynamics. Although there exists a wide range of stochastic SIRD-type epidemic models, these approaches have not been incorporated into economic models so far.Footnote 1

The main contribution of this paper is to examine the economic and epidemic effects of lockdown measures using a calibrated micro-founded stochastic macroeconomic model, which explicitly captures the role different economic activities play with respect to the spread of the coronavirus. In particular, our model captures virus transmissions at the workplace, transmissions caused by interactions between consumers and producers, and transmissions via private contacts. Furthermore, we consider an age-structured population, allowing us to capture age-specific differences with respect to economic activities (e.g., working vs. retired population) and the case fatality rate of COVID-19. In addition to capturing relevant transmission channels, the detailed representation of socioeconomic interaction structures allows us to implement a wide range of specific containment measures in our framework. The model is calibrated based on German micro- and macro-data and is capable of matching to empirical time series, both for economic and for epidemiological indicators, under a policy scenario resembling measures implemented in Germany. Based on this, we investigate different lockdown scenarios by systematically varying key parameters governing the intensity of measures during a lockdown, the degree of relaxation after the lockdown, and the incidence thresholds used to end/reintroduce the lockdown measures.

We show that a policy combining strict lockdown measures with a full opening-up of the economy between lockdowns and a high incidence thresholdFootnote 2 for (re)entering lockdowns is strictly dominated by alternative policies, which either combine a substantially smaller incidence threshold with weaker lockdown measures or implement a continuous light lockdown with only minor restrictions.Footnote 3 The reason that policies alternating between strict lockdowns and full opening perform worse not only with respect to the expected number of casualties, but also with respect to economic losses, is that they induce a higher degree of volatility into the economy. In light of frictions on the labor and product market, this generates higher economic losses compared to scenarios where weaker restrictions induce only smaller, although more persistent, downturns. Similar to others (Acemoglu et al. 2020; Alvarez et al. 2020; Atkeson 2020), we find that there exists a trade-off between economic losses and infection numbers when varying lockdown intensity given a fixed incidence threshold. We also demonstrate that the policies differ substantially with respect to the ex ante uncertainty about the induced economic loss. In particular, the policies which are at the efficiency frontier also tend to give rise to substantially lower variation. Understanding the implications of different policy choices for the variance of policy results seems particularly important in an area like virus containment, where the effectiveness of chosen measures also depends on the policies’ acceptance by the general public. In such a setting, bad initial outcomes might have a detrimental effect on public acceptance of the policy, deteriorating its future effectiveness (Bargain and Aminjonov 2020; Altig et al. 2020). To our knowledge, this paper is the first economic analysis of lockdown policies, explicitly addressing the relationship between policy properties and variance of the resulting economic and epidemiological dynamics.

Since the value of the infection probability of the virus on the one hand is crucial for the epidemic dynamics and on the other hand entails a considerable uncertainty around its exact value, we conduct a robustness check of our results concerning this parameter. The main setting of our analysis is based on the assumption that at a certain point in time, the virus mutates to a more infectious variant, which then spreads in the population simultaneously with the original version. This pattern resembles the situation in many countries during the COVID-19 pandemic. We show that most of our qualitative insights, in particular the appeal of a policy combining a strict lockdown with a weak opening, still apply in scenarios without a mutation (reducing the infection probability) and with a higher infection probability. Clearly, a higher (lower) infectiousness of the virus leads to higher (lower) mortality rates and in consequence also to higher (lower) economic losses. By design, only the continuous weak lockdown is characterized by a stable loss of GDP and becomes more attractive, the higher the infection probability of the virus or its mutation. In the final part of our analysis, we assess the optimal ending point of the policies under a dynamic vaccination rollout. Depending on the lockdown policy, we find that after a vaccination rate of \(25-40\%\) no significant gains in terms of mortality are achieved when prolonging the containment measures. We conclude that in our setting, lockdown policies can be lifted relatively early.

In light of the mechanisms underlying our insights, our qualitative results can be transferred to countries with a health system and economic structure comparable to Germany. In addition, the flexibility of the framework allows the modeler to adjust the parameters related to COVID-19 to analyze potential future pandemics. In fact, the model can easily be re-calibrated to data from other countries or from different pandemics in order to analyze appropriate policies under alternative structural conditions.

Methodologically, our approach combines a SIR-type simulation model with an agent-based macroeconomic model. The design of the economic part of the model, in particular with respect to the structure of the individual decision rules as well as the market interaction protocols, builds strongly on a well-established agent-based macroeconomic framework, namely the Eurace@Unibi model, which has been already used for the analysis of a wide range of economic policy issues (e.g., Dawid et al. (2014, 2018, 2019)). Nevertheless, the model employed here is not an extension of the Eurace@Unibi model, but a separate agent-based model designed for the analysis of the interplay of economic activities and virus transmission, which has also been implemented independently from the Eurace@Unibi model.Footnote 4

Agent-based models have been used to assess the effectiveness of containment policies in purely epidemiological studies (e.g., Adam 2020; Ferguson et al. 2020; LeBaron 2021) and the approach has been applied to address a large variety of macroeconomic research questions and policy analyses in recent years (see, e.g., Foley and Farmer 2009; Dawid and Delli Gatti 2018; Dosi and Roventini 2019, for discussions). By explicitly linking economic activities and transactions to contacts between agents, agent-based economic models are particularly suited for studying the dynamics of virus transmissions in an economy. Only a few other studies have used a unified agent-based model, combining an economic framework with an epidemiological structure in the context of COVID-19. Delli Gatti and Reissl (2020) opt for a relatively smaller model in terms of the number of agents with 2800 households and 300 firms calibrated on an Italian region, Lombardy. Our paper differs from theirs in terms of the main research question. While their focus is on the consequences of different fiscal measures, our main goal is to understand the impacts of several lockdown policies on economic loss and mortality while keeping in place the fiscal measures introduced by the German government. Moreover, we also introduce the occurrence of a virus mutation in a macro-epidemic agent-based model. Sharma et al. (2021) introduce the COVID-19 crisis as exogenous shocks of demand and supply, dropping firm productivity and household consumption propensity, into the Mark-0 agent-based model. Shocks amplitude and duration are the main factors describing the crisis but epidemiological dynamics is not considered. Mandel and Veetil (2020) use a multi-sector disequilibrium model with an agent-based flavor to study the impact of COVID-19 related lockdowns, taking into account input–output data and supply chain effects. However, this paper also does not consider epidemiological dynamics. Mellacher (2020) has a very rich network-based model that enables a detailed treatment of contact spaces such as households, hospitals, or retirement homes. On the other hand, it does not feature shopping contacts which we consider crucial to assess the interconnection of economic and pandemic effects of closures. Silva et al. (2020) present a model to study the effects of various counterfactual containment scenarios on a virtual economy representing Brazil. However, our paper is the first to use such a unified framework for the evaluation of average economic and pandemic effects as well as the associated uncertainty about outcomes under different policy responses to the outbreak of the COVID-19 pandemic.

The paper is organized as follows. In Sect. 2, we provide a short description of the model (a detailed description is given in Appendix A), and in Sect. 3 we describe the set of containment policies considered in our analysis. In Sect. 4, we discuss the calibration of the model and demonstrate the good fit of the model output with time series data from Germany. The main insights from our policy analysis are discussed in Sect. 5, and we end with conclusions and an outlook on potential extensions of the analysis in Sect. 6. In addition to the detailed description of the model, the Appendix contains some results with respect to additional policy variations, statistical test results underlying our findings, and lists of model variables and of parameter values.

2 The model

In this section, we provide a short description of our model, which highlights the overall structure of the economy as well as the crucial assumptions and mechanisms driving the economic and pandemic dynamics. A more detailed and technical presentation of the model is given in Appendix A.

2.1 Economy

The economy consists of firms as well as young and old households. Young households constitute the labor supply of the economy, whereas old households live on a pension that is paid through a pay-as-you-go system. There are three private and one public sector in the economy. We explicitly represent these different sectors in the model in order to be able to capture sectoral differences with respect to firm size and the number of contacts a household has by consuming a product of a particular sector, as well as to analyze the effects of sector-specific reductions in consumption and economic activity due to lockdown measures.Footnote 5 The basic time unit in our model is one day and activities of agents take place daily or periodically, e.g., once a week (household consumption, firm production planning, etc.). The behavioral rules determining the actions of firms and households are based on the literature on macroeconomic agent-based modeling and, in particular to a large extent, resemble the corresponding rules developed for the Eurace@Unibi model (see Dawid et al. (2019)). Figure 1 illustrates the overall model structure.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Summary of model structure

2.1.1 Firms

Firms are distributed across three private sectors: manufacturing (M), service (S), and food (F), where the latter represents all essential products for daily life. A firm i is characterized by a firm-specific productivity level \(A_i\) and employs \(L_{i,t}\) workers in period t to produce a weekly output \(Q_{i,t}\) according to the linear production function \(Q_{i,t} = A_i \; L_{i,t}\).Footnote 6 The firm’s activity and planning cycle is one week and each firm plans and carries out its production at the beginning of each week. The produced quantity replenishes the firm’s inventory stock at the sector-specific mall. At the mall, all producers in that sector offer their products at posted prices. In particular, the firm carries out the following steps:

  1. 1.

    The firm determines the target level of inventory at the beginning of the week based on its adaptive demand expectation and the size of a sector-specific safety buffer, which is determined based on estimated demand volatility.

    The resulting planned production quantity determines the desired size of the firm’s workforce. If the size of the firm’s current workforce is larger than the desired number of employees, the firm dismisses the appropriate number of randomly picked workers.

  2. 2.

    If the firm needs to increase its workforce it opens vacancies and unemployed job seekers skilled to work in the firm’s sector apply. Firms announce their openings in random order and hire on a first-come-first-serve basis. If there are no job seekers at the time of the announcement, the firm is rationed and can only hire again in the following week.

  3. 3.

    Production of output \(Q_{i,t}\) takes place. Products are offered in the sector-specific mall at posted prices. Firms set prices \(p_{i,t}\) by applying mark-up pricing with an endogenous mark-up on unit costs. The mark-up adaptively evolves over time within a fixed interval and depends positively on the firm’s market share.

  4. 4.

    Firms pay wages \(w_i\), which are sector-specific and proportional to the average productivity in the sector, as well as taxes and dividends. Dividends are determined as a fraction \(\zeta \) of net profits, where \(\zeta =1\) if the firm’s liquidity exceeds a threshold and \(\zeta < 1\) otherwise. Dividends and the fixed costs paid by the firms are equally distributed among households to ensure the stock-flow consistency of the model. A firm with negative liquidity declares bankruptcy and exits the market. It dismisses all workers and the firms’ inventory stock is fully written off.Footnote 7

2.1.2 Households

While old households are retired, young households are active on the labor market. Each household has appropriate skills to work in one sector of the economy. The households’ weekly activity sequence is as follows:

  1. 1.

    Unemployed households apply for open positions.

  2. 2.

    Households receive wages, unemployment benefits, pensions as well as dividends and pay taxes.

  3. 3.

    Households determine their consumption budget for the upcoming week according to a buffer-stock saving heuristic, see Deaton (1991). In particular, households spend exactly their weekly net income as long as their current wealth corresponds to a desired wealth-to-income ratio. Otherwise, consumption spending is adjusted such that the wealth-to-income level moves toward its target value. The consumption budget is allocated across the three sectors according to fixed (empirically determined) consumption shares. However, there is a lower bound on the factor by which the consumption budget for food/essential products is allowed to change between consecutive weeks.

  4. 4.

    Each household has a day of the week for each sector \(k \in \{M,S,F\}\) at which she considers to visit the sector-specific mall. The household visits the mall on that day with probability \(p^s_k\), where in the absence of lockdown measures \(p_k^s = 1\) for all sectors k. Upon visiting the mall, the household scans the posted prices in a randomly chosen subset of firms in the sector and chooses the firm to buy from according to a logit choice function based on these prices. The purchased quantity is determined by the household’s consumption budget for that sector.

    If the inventory of a firm at the mall becomes zero during a week, the firm is no longer considered by households in their consumption choice until the inventory is filled up again. If there are no active firms in the mall when a household h visits the mall or if the chosen firm is not able to supply to the total amount demanded, then the consumer is rationed and returns to the mall again the following day. All parts of the foreseen weekly consumption budget for sector k which have not been spent after that second shopping day, are added to the household’s savings.

2.1.3 Public sector

Besides the three private sectors, there is also a public sector operated by the government with a constant number of government offices. The public sector provides administrative services that are not sold on the goods market.Footnote 8 Each public sector office employs a set of civil servants that only changes over time if an employee dies. The government collects income and profit taxes to finance the wage bill of the public employees and to pay unemployment benefits, pensions, and potentially lockdown-related transfers to individuals and firms. Unemployment benefits are based on the last wage of an unemployed worker with replacement rate \(\nu \). Pensions are uniform for all old households and are determined as a constant percentage of the average wage in the economy. Households employed in the public sector earn a fixed wage \(w^P\). The government adjusts the tax rate over time in order to keep the public account at a given target level.

2.2 Virus transmission

Virus transmission is modeled by explicitly tracking contacts between agents and potential infection chains. Following a standard SIRD approach households can be in one of the four states: susceptible, infected, recovered, or deceased (see, e.g., Hethcote 2000). In the absence of any policy measures, a susceptible household is infected with the homogeneous infection probability \(p_{inf}\) at each contact with an infectious agent. Due to policy measures, this probability is reduced to \((1 - \xi ) p_{inf}\), where the value of \(\xi \) depends on the type of measures implemented (see below). After infection, an agent first enters a homogeneous latency period of length \(t_{ltn}\), followed by a period where the agent is infectious (length \(t_{inf}\)). Following this, agents enter the post-infectious phase, and recover after \(\bar{t}_{rec}\) periods, unless they pass away before that. While being infected, a household of age a dies with a case fatality rate \(q_t^{a}\) with \(a \in \{y,o\}\). The rate does not only depend on the age of the household, but also on the degree of utilization of intensive care units in the economy at time t. In particular, depending on the degree of over-utilization, the age-specific fatality rate is a weighted average between a regular fatality rate \(\bar{q}_l^{a}\) achieved with under-utilized intensive care units and a fatality rate \(\bar{q}_h^{a}\) that would be achieved if no intensive care capacities would be available. Formally

$$\begin{aligned} q_t^{a} = \left[ \frac{\min (n^{icu},u^{icu} \cdot \vert \textbf{I}_t\vert )}{u^{icu} \cdot \vert \textbf{I}_t\vert }\right] \bar{q}_l^{a} + \left[ 1-\frac{\min (n^{icu},u^{icu} \cdot \vert \textbf{I}_t\vert )}{u^{icu} \cdot \vert \textbf{I}_t\vert }\right] \bar{q}_h^{a} \end{aligned}$$
(1)

where \(n^{icu}\), \(u^{icu}\), \(\textbf{I}_t\) are, respectively, the number of intensive care beds available, the fraction of infected individuals in need of intensive care and the set of infected agents at t.Footnote 9 If a household passes away, the current savings of this household are inherited by a randomly selected living household to ensure stock-flow consistency of the model. In case the intensive care units are under-utilized, the fatality rate only depends on the agents’ age-group. If, however, the demand for intensive care units exceeds the availability, the fatality rate increases proportionally to the size of the shortfall.

2.2.1 Virus mutation

Based on empirical observations during the COVID-19 pandemic, we assume that at day \(t^{mut}\) a new and more contagious virus mutation emerges. For a household infected with the new variant, the individual infection probability \(p_{inf}^{mut}\) of the mutant is higher compared to the original virus, while the remaining epidemiological parameters are the same as for the original virus. At \(t^{mut}\) a small number of infected households switches to the virus mutation and afterward there are two coexisting virus strains spreading across the population, where upon being infected a household inherits the type from the infecting agent.Footnote 10

Fig. 2
figure 2

Summary of transmission channels

2.2.2 Social interactions

Contacts between households may take place on three different occasions, each potentially contributing to the propagation of the virus (see Fig. 2):

  1. (i)

    Employed households have contact to a number of co-workers at their employer every day. More precisely, every worker h employed in sector \(k \in \{M,S,F,P\}\), apart from those working from home or on short time workFootnote 11, meets every day t a set of \(N_{h,t}^{w}\) randomly selected colleagues employed at the same firm, respectively, public office. The number of meetings on a given day, \(N_{h,t}^{w}\), is determined by independent random draws from a uniform distribution between 0 and \(n_k^w\). We allow the upper bound \(n_k^w, \ k \in \{M,S,F,P\}\) to vary between sectors.

  2. (ii)

    During their consumption activities, households have contacts with other agents visiting the same mall on the same day. For the service sector, this also includes contacts during the consumption of a service (e.g., at a restaurant or a fitness studio). More precisely, for each sector k the parameter \(n_{k}^c\) determines the maximum number of possible meetings on one shopping day and, similar to above, for each household visiting a mall in sector k at t a specific value \({\bar{N}}_{h,k,t}^{c}\), is drawn randomly between 0 and \(n_k^c\). The actual number of people met by a household h visiting a mall of sector k is then given \({\bar{N}}_{h,k,t}^{c}\) multiplied by the ratio between the actual number of visitors to that mall and the number to be expected if an equal fraction of all households visit the mall every day of the week. This formulation captures that fewer interactions, and therefore also fewer infections occur during shopping or consumption of services if households reduce their consumption activities. Also, it allows to capture that the average number of interactions during consumption might vary substantially between sectors.

  3. (iii)

    Agents also have social contacts not directly related to economic activities. We distinguish between the frequencies of intra- and inter-generational contacts for the different age-groups. In particular, the number of contacts for each type of meeting of agents across age-groups is drawn from a uniform distribution whose upper bound \(n^p_{a,a'}, \ a,a' \in \{y, o\}\) reflects the cross age interaction patterns, based on empirical data.

This approach to modeling social interaction implies that the actual number of contacts for a household is stochastic with sector- and age-specific expected values that have been informed by empirical data. It should also be noted that we assume that agents do not change their behavior and their contact patterns after infection. This simplifying assumption is based on the observations that a large fraction of infected individuals do not show symptomsFootnote 12 and that at least in the initial months of the pandemic no large-scale testing facilities were available.

3 Policy measures

3.1 Containment measures

The containment measures addressed in our policy analysis are inspired by a set of measures implemented in different countries after the outbreak of COVID-19 (Cheng et al. 2020) and can be grouped into four categories:

  1. (i)

    Individual prevention measures reducing the infection probability at face-to-face contacts between an infected and a susceptible agent from \(p_{inf}\) to \((1-\xi ) \ p_{inf}\), respectively, \(p_{inf}^{mut}\) to \((1-\xi ) \ p_{inf}^{mut}\), with \(\xi \in (0,1)\). These measures include keeping a minimum physical distance, improved measures of sanitation, and wearing face coverings.

  2. (ii)

    Social distancing measures reducing social interactions in the private context either through contact restrictions imposed by the government or through a consensual change in the behavior of individuals. Studies show that there has been a substantial reduction in the number of social contacts in Germany after the outbreak of COVID-19 (e.g., Lehrer et al. 2020). In our model, social distancing is captured by a reduction in the average number of daily intra- and inter-generational social contacts.

  3. (iii)

    Reduction in contacts at the workplace, by allowing a sector-specific fraction \(h_k^{ho}\) of employees to work from home (see Fadinger and Schymik 2020; Möhring et al. 2020).

  4. (iv)

    Reduction in consumption activities, by reducing the sector-specific weekly shopping probabilities \(p^{s}_k\). Such a reduction might be induced by restrictions from the government (lockdown), or by voluntary changes in individual consumption behavior due to public information about potential infection risks. More precisely, we assume that the weekly shopping probability during lockdown is reduced to

    $$\begin{aligned} p^{s,l} = (1,1,1) - \alpha ^l (\Delta p^{s,l}_M, \Delta p^{s,l}_S, 0). \end{aligned}$$
    (2)

    The parameter \(\alpha ^l\) governs the intensity of the lockdown and \(\Delta p^{s,l}_M, \Delta p^{s,l}_S\) are calibrated such that the intensity of the lockdown measures taken in Germany in March 2020 corresponds to \(\alpha ^l = 1\). Shopping probabilities in the food and essential goods sector are not reduced during lockdowns. In contrast to measures (i)–(iii), the reduction in consumption activities has a direct negative impact on economic activity. In order to capture policies that include partial reduction in consumption also in periods without an actual lockdown in place, we introduce a second parameter \(\alpha ^o\), governing the degree of opening. The sector-specific weekly shopping probability in periods without lockdown (as long as the containment policy is active) is given by

    $$\begin{aligned} p^{s,o} = (1,1,1) - \alpha ^o (\Delta p^{s,l}_M, \Delta p^{s,l}_S, 0). \end{aligned}$$
    (3)

3.2 Economic support programs

We assume that economic support measures accompany the virus containment policies in order to counteract the economic disruptions and to keep the number of insolvencies low:

  1. (i)

    Under the short-time work scheme firms put a fraction \(q^{st}\) of employees on short-time work. Employees on short time receive a fraction \(\varphi < 1\) of their regular wage paid by a transfer from the public account.

  2. (ii)

    Under the bailout policy, the government bails out any firm with negative liquidity in a given period balancing the firm’s account with a transfer from the public account, thereby avoiding bankruptcy.

In our policy analysis below, we assume that both measures are activated at the time of the first lockdown, and then maintained till the containment policy is lifted. As shown in Basurto et al. (2020), the qualitative findings discussed in Sect. 5.2 carry over also to scenarios without economic support programs in place.

4 Model calibration

Our basic calibration approach is to determine the values of the majority of the parameters based on direct empirical evidence from different data sources and calibrate the remaining parameters, for which no such direct evidence is available, in a way that the model output well matches empirical time series of key variables related to the pandemic and economic indicators in Germany between the outbreak of the pandemic and the end of the third quarter of 2020. Here, we provide a summary of the key aspects of this approach, and details of the calibration of the model are provided in Appendix A.4. It is based on demographic and statistical data from Germany, as well as empirical studies on age-structured social interaction patterns. We target key aggregate economic indicators, e.g., per capita GDP, unemployment rate, and the value of the \(R_t\) coefficient for the coronavirus in the absence of any countermeasures.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Comparison of simulation output with empirical data for Germany. Blue solid lines show the average over 50 Monte Carlo runs, black dotted lines plus–minus one standard deviation bands across Monte Carlo runs. Green solid lines show empirical counterparts based on epidemiological data from Johns Hopkins University (Johns Hopkins University 2020) for Germany from March 9, 2020 (day 0) to the end of the third quarter (day 205), scaled to a population of 100.000 inhabitants and adjusted by a detection rate. Containment and lockdown measures are introduced after 14 days into our simulation (corresponding to March 23, 2020) and are lifted on day 63 (May 11, 2020) (Cheng et al. 2020). (a), Accumulated number of infected. (b), weekly smoothed \(R_t\) value (c), casualties as a percentage of the population. (d), monthly GDP loss as a percentage of the baseline GDP with green dots showing quarterly GDP loss (Eurostat 2020a) (e), percentage of workers in short-time program with green dots showing estimated number of workers in short-time program relative to the size of the active labor force for April to August in Germany (Bundesagentur für Arbeit 2020). (f), excess savings per household relative to baseline GDP per capita with green dots showing empirical excess savings relative to baseline GDP (ECB 2021) (color figure online)

We initialize the model with \(m_0 = 100.000\) households and \(n_0 = 3780\) firms (private and public). The number of households is chosen to balance the trade-off between having a sufficiently large population size and technical limitations. The total number of firms, instead, has been chosen to match the relation between the size of the working population and the number of private firms in the German economy. The initial population state we use for all our simulations has been generated by running our model for a burn-in phase of 2300 periods. Without the appearance of the virus and any change in the policy parameters, the model exhibits stationary dynamics of the economic key variables like GDP and unemployment starting from this initial state.

We use data from the German statistical office on demographic structure, sectoral distributions of productivity and consumption spending, average firm size, and the average unemployment rate. The sector-specific fractions of workers eligible for working from home are based on empirical studies by Fadinger and Schymik (2020) and Möhring et al. (2020). Parameterization of behavioral rules are taken from the well-established models in the agent-based macroeconomic literature (see, e.g., Dawid et al. 2019). Additional economic parameters, like the firms’ sector-specific inventory buffers or mark-up ranges are calibrated to generate a stationary GDP per capita and unemployment rate that reasonably match the German economy before the pandemic. In particular, for the pre-pandemic period, the model generates an annual GDP per capita of 43.013€ and an unemployment rate of \(3.98\%\) (average over 50 runs) compared to an annual GDP per capita (Eurostat 2020a) of 41.350€ and an average unemployment rate (Eurostat 2020b) of \(3.2\%\) in 2019.

Epidemiological parameters, like fatality rates, intensive care utilizationFootnote 13, and the detection rate, are taken from German data (mainly from the Robert Koch Institut), whereas the parameters determining the duration of latency and infectiousness after being infected are based on World Health Organization data. Our representation of a virus mutation arising after about 6 months is based on data about the ’\(\alpha \)-mutation’ of SARS-CoV-2 detected in Great Britain in September 2020. The (age-structured) number of social contacts associated with different activities is taken from survey studies on this topic (Mossong et al. 2008). The calibration of the parameters describing the containment measures, the sector-specific effects on consumption and on the reduction in contacts is based on German data on policy interventions, societal activities, and economic losses during and after the first lockdown in March 2020 (see Appendix A.4 for all parameter choices and sources). The individual contact infection probability \(p_{inf}\) is calibrated to match an \(R_0\) value of 2.5 (without any containment policy), in accordance with empirical evidence (Read et al. 2020). The effectiveness of individual prevention measures \(\xi \), for which no direct empirical observations are available, is calibrated by targeting key properties of infection dynamics in Germany over a time span of 6 months. In particular, we use two separate values for this parameter: For the first lockdown phase starting on March 9, 2020, we use \(\xi ^l=0.625\), and for the opening-up phase after May 11, 2020, we use \(\xi ^o=0.55\). In Fig. 3, we compare the simulation output of the model under policies resembling German measures (blue) with actual German data (green) from March 9, 2020 to the end of the third quarter of 2020.Footnote 14 Although only three free parameters (\(\xi ^l, \xi ^o, q^{st}\)) were calibrated to target these empirical time series, the generated data is consistent with its empirical counterpart, both with respect to levels and dynamic patterns. This applies to infections and mortality (Fig. 3a–c) as well as to the time series of economic indicators, like the GDP loss, the number of workers in short-time program, or dynamics of households’ excess savings relative to the pre-crisis level (Fig. 3d–f).

5 Policy analysis

Having established the ability of our model to qualitatively and also quantitatively reproduce German epidemiological and economic time series under a policy scenario mirroring actual measures taken in Germany, we will now explore the epidemiological and economic implications of alternative policies. Our analysis begins in Sect. 5.1 with a policy scenario in which we only consider measures without direct economic effects. This part demonstrates that restricting attention to such policies is not sufficient to keep the number of infected at a level to avoid over-utilization of intensive care unit capacities. Based on this, we focus on our main analysis in Sect. 5.2 on lockdown policies that are associated with direct economic restrictions and compare the effects of different designs of such policies. In Sect. 5.3, we run the same policy analysis but first, excluding the emergence of a more contagious virus mutation and second, increasing the infection probability by \(25\%\) to assess the robustness of the derived policy results. In Sect. 5.4, we investigate the optimal phase-out of our main policies under a dynamic vaccination rollout.

5.1 Policies without direct economic impact

An important question is whether the spreading of the virus can be reduced with containment measures not directly interfering with economic activities in the sense of closing stores or reducing the possibility to consume services. In order to address this question, we consider three policy scenarios: first, a scenario where no containment measures are taken at all; second, the introduction of only individual prevention measures; and third the combination of these individual prevention measures with working from home.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Dynamics. Solid lines show averages over 50 Monte Carlo runs, dotted lines plus-minus one standard deviation bands across Monte Carlo runs. a Dynamics of currently infected individuals and b total casualties as well as c GDP per capita and d unemployment rate for the scenarios with no policy measures (blue), only individual prevention measures (orange) and individual prevention measures in combination with working from home (green). The black dotted line in panel a indicates the upper bound on the number of infected under which the intensive care capacities are still not fully used (color figure online)

Figure 4 shows the dynamics of the percentages of the population currently infected and deceased. The curve of infected individuals in the absence of any measures (blue) follows a steep hump-shaped pattern well known from standard SIRD models (Hethcote 2000). Due to herd immunity, the virus is eliminated after approximately 120 days but the associated mortality is about 1.6%. This illustrates that our transmission model is producing reasonable, characteristic epidemiological dynamics.

To see the effect of individual prevention measures in our model, we analyze a setup in which only \(\xi \) increases to the calibrated benchmark value of \(\xi ^l = 0.625\) 2 weeks after the appearance of the virus. The introduction of the individual prevention measures (orange) strongly reduces the speed of the diffusion of the virus and the maximum number of infected. Complementing individual prevention measures with working from home (green) reinforces these effects and average mortality can be reduced by a factor of approximately 10 compared to the scenario without any containment. Nevertheless, we observe in Fig. 4a that the curve indicating the average number of infected crosses the black dotted line, which represents the upper bound of infected compatible with intensive care unit capacity, both in the scenario with only individual prevention measures as well as in the scenario where working from home is introduced in addition. Hence, these measures are not sufficient to ensure that the number of infected stays below the intensive care capacity.

Considering the GDP and unemployment dynamics shown in Fig. 4c and d, it is confirmed that these measures are not associated with any direct economic costs.Footnote 15 A crucial assumption in this respect is that in our setting productivity of workers is not reduced when they work from home. The slight decrease in GDP and increase in unemployment around period 100 in the scenario without containment measures is due to the reduction in demand induced by the large mortality. Since the majority of deceased are old agents, who are not part of the workforce and receive their income entirely through transfers, the reduction in consumption spending induced by the death of these agents is partly offset by a reduction in income tax and the resulting increase in the consumption budget of the remaining population. The adaptation of the tax rate is, however, sluggish such that the pandemic wave nevertheless induces a contraction with some increase in unemployment, which then triggers negative follow-up effects on employment and slows further downward adjustment of GDP even after the pandemic wave is over.

Fig. 5
figure 5

Timeline underlying the policy analysis

5.2 Policies with direct economic impact

In the following analysis, we focus on the design of containment measures with direct economic impact. In order to compare different policies we use two main indicators: (i) virus mortality, measured as the percentage of the population deceased due to the virus 24 months after the virus outbreak and (ii) the average percentage loss in GDP (relative to the pre-virus level) during this time interval. Similar to the default policy scenario (Fig. 3), we assume that 2 weeks after the initial occurrence of the virus at \(t=0\), individual preventive measures, social distancing, working from home, and lockdown measures are activated.Footnote 16 The design of the lockdown policy is then characterized by the following three key parameters, which are systematically varied in our analysis:

  1. (i)

    Intensity of the lockdown reducing the shopping probability: \(\alpha ^l\) [see eq. (2)].

  2. (ii)

    Reduction in weekly shopping probability in periods without lockdown if the virus is still active: \(\alpha ^o\) (see eq. (3)).

  3. (iii)

    Incidence threshold \(\beta ^l\): the lockdown stage is re-activated if the reported number of weekly newly infected per 100.000 households rises above \(\beta ^l\).

As mentioned above, the benchmark policy resembling the German scenario in Sect. 4 corresponds to \((\alpha ^l, \alpha ^o, \beta ^l) = (1,0,50)\).Footnote 17 During the opening-up phase, we assume that the working from home measure remains active. After approximately 5 months, we introduce a virus mutation with an infection probability increased by \(50\%\). Moreover, all runs are based on the assumption that 18 months after the first occurrence of the virus, a vaccine has been developed and a sufficient percentage of the population has been vaccinated to prevent any further transmissions of the virus. Hence, at that point \(p_{\inf }\) and \(p_{inf}^{mut}\) are set to zero and all containment measures are lifted. Since a full economic recovery might still need some time even after all restrictions have been removed, our analysis covers a time window of 24 months after the first introduction of lockdown measures. Figure 5 summarizes the timeline underlying our policy analysis. For each considered policy scenario, we carry out 50 simulation runs of the model in order to capture the variance of the emerging dynamics.

Fig. 6
figure 6

Effects of variations of key policy parameters. All points correspond to averages across the 50 runs. GDP loss [%] on the x-axis measured as loss averaged over simulation time span of 728 periods (24 months) as a percentage of baseline and mortality [%] on the y-axis expressed as a percentage of population

The main results from our analysis are summarized in Fig. 6, which shows the average GDP loss and total mortality after 24 months (mean over the 50 runs) under a systematic variation of the policy parameters. Starting from point A, corresponding to the calibrated German policy scenario (1, 0, 50), we systematically vary the key parameters \((\alpha ^l, \alpha ^o, \beta ^l)\). First, along the black line we decrease the incidence threshold \(\beta ^l\) for entering a lockdown, reaching a policy (1, 0, 5) in point B, whereas for the highest point we increase \(\beta ^l\) to 100. Second, along red lines (solid and dashed) we decrease (left arrow) or increase (right arrow) the intensity of the lockdown, \(\alpha ^l\), with a step size of 0.25. In the following analysis we will in particular consider the policy (0.5, 0, 5), labeled as C, which combines a low lockdown threshold with weak restrictions during the lockdown. Finally, along blue lines (solid and dashed) we increase the restrictions in the opening-up phase, \(\alpha ^o\), in steps of size 0.25. Hence, point D (0.5, 0.5, 5) represents a policy of continuous weak restrictions of economic activity. Figure 7 shows the dynamics of newly infected (panel a) and per capita GDP (panel b) for the four key policy scenarios corresponding to points A–D. Table 1 contains mean values and standard deviations for key indicators, such as the duration of the lockdown or the public deficit, across the batch runs for each of the four key policies. In Tables 10 and 11 in Appendix D we provide information on the statistical significance of the differences in induced GDP loss and mortality between the key policies based on Mann–Whitney U tests.

Fig. 7
figure 7

Dynamics. Evolution of the a current number of infected and b the GDP per capita for the five policy scenarios (A: green; B: blue; C: red; D: purple). Solid lines indicate batch run means and dotted lines indicate plus/minus one standard deviation (color figure online)

Table 1 Comparison of policy results

Based on these Figures and Tables we derive four qualitative insights about the implication of different types of lockdown policies.

Result 1

Policies with a continuous ‘weak lockdown’ dominate policies with switches between strong lockdown and full opening (C, D vs A).

Figure 6 shows that policy scenario A is clearly dominated by policies C and D, which both result in lower expected values of mortality and lower GDP loss. Considering the very high average lockdown duration under policy C, it is hardly surprising that the effect of this policy is close to that of policy D, which essentially implements a weak lockdown throughout the entire 18 months in which the virus is active. As can be seen in Fig. 7 the main economic advantage of these policies is that they induce a much weaker initial downturn, compared to a policy with a strong initial lockdown (such as A). The reduction in economic activity caused by strong lockdown measures has an immediate negative impact on a firm’s production planning and household’s wage income. Hence, even after lockdown measures have been lifted, the adjustment of consumption spending and production plans needs time and in combination with (labor market) frictions this implies a relatively slow economic recovery.Footnote 18 Therefore, under policies characterized by strong lockdown-induced downturns, accumulated GDP loss grows in a convex way with the size of these downturns. Hence, avoiding the large costs associated with a strong initial reduction in economic activity induces smaller economic losses, even if the constraints have to be preserved for an extended period of time, as in policy D. Figure 7a shows that implementing only weak lockdown measures leads to a larger initial peak and a delayed decrease in the infection numbers, compared to a strong lockdown (A). However, the continuous application of lockdown measures prevents a second wave and hence overall mortality in policies C and D is below that of A. Finally, it should be noted that, due to the induced strong and repeated economic downturns, policy A also results in a larger increase in the public deficit compared to policies C and D (Table 1). These differences in public deficit are mainly due to more extensive use of the short-time work scheme in policy scenarios A and B, whereas there is only a minor difference in bailout expenditures between the scenarios.Footnote 19

Result 2

Two trade-offs emerge. For a given lockdown intensity \(\alpha ^l\), decreasing the lockdown threshold \(\beta ^l\) induces lower mortality but increases economic losses (A vs. B). For a given lockdown threshold \(\beta ^l\), a variation of the intensity \(\alpha ^l\) results in a trade-off between mortality and GDP loss (B vs. C).

In terms of infection dynamics (Fig. 7a), a higher threshold causes a visible second wave which is absent for a lower threshold. A threshold of \(\beta ^l=50\) results in two lockdowns for most runs (Table 1), which are necessary in response to resurgence of the virus. In contrast, policy B with threshold of \(\beta ^l= 5\) causes numerous lockdowns and accumulates a longer total duration in lockdowns over the whole time span. These repeated lockdowns keep the number of infected low, which explains the substantial reduction in mortality relative to policy A. In terms of GDP, both policies are characterized by a strong initial downturn and the trajectories only begin to deviate from each other in the recovery phase. Under a low threshold (policy B) the economy returns earlier into the next lockdown, while afterward the trajectories again evolve similarly until the end. Overall, this short period in which policy A recovers considerably stronger is enough such that policy B results in significantly higher economic costs (Table 10).

Our second trade-off, the observation that reducing the lockdown intensity leads to lower economic losses but higher mortality, can not only be derived from the comparison of policies B and C, which both have a threshold of \(\beta ^l = 5\), but also for \(\beta ^l = 50\) by considering the dotted red curve moving to the upper left from point A in Fig. 6. The dynamics in Fig. 7a illustrate that less reduction in consumption activity (policy C vs. B) leads to more infections and higher mortality. Considering the GDP dynamics (Fig. 7b), one can observe that the stricter lockdown of policy B imposes a strong initial shock on the economy and forces the GDP trajectory on a lower path compared to policy C over the entire course of the simulation. Comparing the slopes of the red and the black line in Fig. 6 clearly shows that the trade-off between reducing economic loss and increasing mortality is less pronounced if the intensity of the lockdown is varied rather than the lockdown threshold. Hence, we obtain the following observation.

Result 3

The increase in expected mortality associated with a given decrease in GDP loss is smaller if the reduction in GDP loss is obtained through a reduction in lockdown intensity \(\alpha ^l\) compared to an increase in the threshold \(\beta ^l\).

Together, Results 1-3 identify a kind of ‘efficiency frontier’ spanned by policies of varying intensity of lockdowns with low threshold (C,B). As one might expect, the frontier is characterized by a trade-off between mortality and economic loss, but policies switching between strict lockdowns and full openings are above the frontier if the threshold for entering a lockdown in such policies is high (A). A policy with a continuous weak lockdown (D), on the other hand, is close to the frontier and dominates policies with high incidence thresholds like A. Whereas so far we have only considered the expected effects of the different policies, in the next result we consider the ex ante uncertainty about mortality and GDP loss, i.e., the variance of these indicators across runs.

Result 4

Similar to the trade-offs before, policies differ significantly with respect to the variance of resulting GDP loss and mortality. Effects of policies with a ‘weak lockdown’ (C, D) can be predicted with higher certainty than for policies inducing switches between strong lockdown and full opening (A, B) in terms of GDP loss. In turn, for these policies (C,D) the overall mortality is harder to predict in comparison with policies A and B.

Considering the standard deviation for the different indicators across batch runs, Table 1 shows that the GDP loss induced by policies with weak lockdowns (C,D) varies much less across runs than the GDP loss under policies A and B. Put differently, the economic implications of policies C and D are much better predictable compared to alternative approaches. The downside for this difference is that under policies C and D the variance of the dynamics of infected is substantially larger compared to policies A and B. In particular, for policy A the timing for the second wave is predictable while for policy B, the second wave is prevented by many small lockdowns without varying strongly across runs. In contrast, under policies C and D second large waves (slowly) develop for some of the runs and hence the infection dynamics are harder to predict. Overall, a trade-off in uncertainty emerges with a higher prediction accuracy in GDP loss (C,D) or in mortality (A,B).

5.3 Effects of a variation of the virus infectiousness

Whereas in the previous section we examined the relationship between different lockdown policy designs and the (ex ante) uncertainty of the policy effects with respect to our two key indicators, in this section we focus on the question of how robust our insights about policy effects are with respect to a variation in the infectiousness of the virus and with respect to the absence of the virus mutation. Examining such robustness seems important since in particular at the beginning of the pandemic data about the basic infection probability \(p_{inf}\) and the effectiveness of individual protection measures (\(\xi \)) is hardly available. Hence, one should account for substantial uncertainty about these parameters. Furthermore, the occurrence of (more infectious) mutations can hardly be predicted both with respect to the timing of such an occurrence and the properties of the mutations. Although we do not carry out an extensive exploration of the effects of different pandemic scenarios, we develop some intuition on how strongly the effects of our main policies change under such variations by comparing two alternative scenarios with our default scenario considered so far. First, we consider a counterfactual scenario in which no mutations occur after the initial outbreak of the pandemic, such that throughout the entire considered time horizon of 18 months only the original version of the virus with the calibrated infection probability \(p_{inf}\) is active. Compared to our default scenario where a more infectious mutation occurs after several months, this captures a situation with a weaker diffusion of the virus. We refer to it as the no mutation scenario. Second, we study a scenario where the value of \(p_{inf}\) is increased by 25% compared to our standard calibration and again no mutation occurs. Compared to our default scenario, this corresponds to a situation where initially the infectiousness of the virus is larger, but in the long run it is lower. (The infectiousness of the mutation in our default scenario is 50% above \(p_{inf}\).) We refer to this as the higher \(p_{inf}\) scenario.

Fig. 8
figure 8

Comparison for scenarios a without mutation and b with higher \(p_{inf}\). All points correspond to averages across the 50 runs. GDP loss [%] on the x-axis measured as loss averaged over simulation time span of 728 periods (24 months) as a percentage of baseline and mortality [%] on the y-axis expressed as a percentage of population

Figure 8 shows the average values of mortality and GDP loss (across batch runs) under the different policies in the two scenarios. Hence, the panels correspond to Fig. 6 for the default scenario. It can be seen that several of the obtained insights remain valid. In particular, both variations of \(\alpha ^l\) and \(\beta ^l\) are associated with a trade-off between reduction in mortality and GDP loss (Result 2) and the curve associated with a variation of the lockdown threshold \(\beta ^l\) (black line) is substantially steeper than the line associated with a variation of the lockdown intensity \(\alpha ^l\) (red line), see Result 3. Also, the insight that a policy with a low threshold and weak lockdown (C) dominates a policy with a larger threshold and stronger lockdown (Result 1) carries over to both alternative pandemic scenarios. The comparison between our benchmark policy A and a policy of continuous weak lockdown (D), however, changes if we move from our default scenario to the no mutation case. Whereas the mortality is still significantly smaller under policy D compared to A, in the no mutation scenario the GDP loss under A is smaller compared to the loss arising under the continuous weak lockdown D. Actually, the GDP loss induced under D hardly differs between the default and the no mutation scenario, whereas the loss under policy A is substantially smaller if no mutation occurs. This is not surprising, since under policy D the economic restrictions remain unchanged until all measures are lifted after 18 months, regardless of infection dynamics. Under the benchmark policy A, the duration of the lockdown is much smaller in the no mutation scenario than in the default case, since without the occurrence of the mutation the second wave on average occurs later and a third wave is avoided.

Fig. 9
figure 9

Box plots for the scenarios mutation (default, blue), no mutation (red) and higher \(p_{inf}\) (green) over 50 batch runs. a, c GDP loss [%] measured as loss averaged over simulation time span of 728 periods (24 months) as a percentage of baseline and b, d mortality [%] expressed as a percentage of population (color figure online)

In Fig. 9, the distribution of outcomes (across the 50 batch runs) under policies A and D are compared across the three considered pandemic scenarios. Comparing panels (a) and (c) illustrates that a continuous weak lockdown policy does not only ensure a low variance of the GDP loss across runs, i.e., good ex ante predictability of the effect on GDP, but also exhibits low sensitivity of the induced GDP loss with respect to a variation in the pandemic scenario. The benchmark policy A induces significantly larger GDP losses compared to C under the default and higher \(p_{inf}\) scenarios, but, as discussed above, leads to smaller losses in the no mutation scenario. The variation of mortality across the three scenarios, on the other hand, is similar under both policies.

5.4 Policy phase-out under vaccination rollout

In our main analysis, we assumed that a vaccine is administered instantaneously to the entire population and works with 100% effectiveness. This means the pandemic ends abruptly as soon as the vaccine becomes available. However, in the real world, production, delivery, and administering take a considerable amount of time, a fraction of the population is not willing to participate in vaccination programs and vaccines are not 100% effective. Furthermore, vaccine effectiveness tends to vanish over time. In this subsection, we examine the effects of a constrained vaccination program, where vaccine administration is limited to a certain number of doses per day. A crucial policy question in this setting is to find the optimal stopping point at which virus containment measures should be terminated. For the sake of simplicity, we combine the administration of the first and possible second dose to a single point in time. All parameters of the vaccination program have been set to values, which resembles the situation in Germany. Compared to our default setting vaccinations start at an earlier point in time (day 338), vaccination speed is 0.337% of the population per day and 75% of the population are willing to get vaccinated. This implies that the vaccination rollout is completed on day 561, which corresponds exactly to the day at which in our default model the entire population becomes immune to the virus. According to procedures in most countries, old agents get vaccinated with priority. We assume that vaccine effectiveness declines at a constant rate of 0.34%-points per day, which implies that the effectiveness after 6 months is 23% in line with empirical data (Nordström et al. 2022).

Fig. 10
figure 10

Effect of terminating measures early with vaccination rollout. Lines A-D correspond to the four policy scenarios (Table 2). Measures are terminated after 0, 25, 40 or 100% of the population have been offered a vaccination. For detailed data on GDP loss, mortality, lockdown duration, number of lockdowns and public account deficit, see Appendix C

Figure 10 shows the average GDP loss and mortality under the modified vaccination program for the four policies (A-D) discussed above. Virus containment measures were terminated after 0%, 25%, 40% or 100% of the population had the opportunity to get vaccinated. In the 100% scenario, the administration of the last dose coincides with the vaccination day from our main analysis. Hence, this scenario can be used, to assess the impact of explicitly modeling the vaccine rollout rather than making the stylized assumption that the entire population becomes vaccinated on a certain day, as we did in the previous sections. In all scenarios A-D, both mortality and GDP loss are significantly lower when the vaccine has to be rolled out, compared to our main analysis. The lower mortality can be explained by the fact, that the vaccination program starts earlier with priority for the old age-group. GDP loss is lower, because virus spread is reduced, well before all agents have been vaccinated and the economy therefore spends less time in lockdown. The relationship between the four policy scenarios, however, is qualitatively similar to our main analysis, indicating that our results also apply to a more realistic scenario with a vaccination rollout and decreasing vaccine effectiveness over time. Concerning the optimal point in time for containment measures to be phased out, Fig. 10 shows that in all policy scenarios, mortality is significantly higher, if containment measures are terminated as soon as the vaccination program starts. However, there is no significant difference in mortality between ending the measures after vaccination is complete (100%) and ending the measures once 40% of the population have been offered a vaccination. GDP loss on the other hand is significantly higher in the 100% case, suggesting that virus containment measures should be terminated earlier. This result is driven by two factors: 1) old agents, which have a much higher case mortality rate are given priority and therefore get vaccinated first, 2) virus spread is already noticeably reduced if a fraction of the population is immune. This is particularly helpful in the low-threshold setting (B-D), where infection numbers have been brought down to low values, before lifting the measures.

6 Conclusions

In this paper, we develop an agent-based model capable of jointly describing the epidemic and economic effects of measures aimed at containing the COVID-19 pandemic. We show that the calibrated model replicates the economic and epidemic dynamics in Germany in the first 6 months after the COVID-19 outbreak well and employ the model to compare the effects of different alternative policy approaches. Our analysis identifies an efficiency frontier of policies with respect to induced expected virus mortality and GDP loss and shows that policies on that frontier are characterized by small incidence thresholds and that policies with continuous weak lockdowns are close to that frontier as well. Policies characterized by switches between strict lockdowns and full openings based on large incidence thresholds are strictly dominated by frontier policies and also give rise to substantially larger ex ante uncertainty about the actual economic loss to be induced by the policy. We also show that most of these insights are robust with respect to variations of the pandemic scenarios.

Whereas these results have been obtained in calibration of the model based on German data and the COVID-19 pandemic, the mechanisms underlying our findings clearly apply more generally such that these policy insights should carry over to other economies with a similar structure as well as to other pandemics driven by similar kinds of virus transmission.

From a methodological perspective, this approach, which explicitly captures individual interactions related to economic activities, allows us to jointly study the epidemiological and economic effects of different containment measures and to shed light on the interplay between economic activity and propagation of the virus. Due to the flexible microstructure of our model and the explicit representation of virus transmission through interactions between agents, our analysis can be extended in many directions, such as incorporating heterogeneity of infection probabilities across individuals, a social network structure, or different vaccination strategies.