1 Introduction

VAT has become a major source of tax revenue in most countries of the world not least due to certain advantages in tax enforcement. In particular, within the formal sector, the common invoice-credit form of calculating VAT provides a self-enforcing incentive structure (e.g., Pomeranz, 2015). Even in countries that are characterized by a large informal sector, the built-in withholding-tax feature has been shown to facilitate tax enforcement (Waseem, 2022). However, since taxes are refunded on inputs, VAT is susceptible to fraud. This is experienced in particular in the EU, where the so-called missing-trader (MT) fraud exploits the fact that “tax frontiers” have been removed in the EU’s common market. As exports are zero-rated and no import VAT is levied by the importing country, imports from other EU countries enter the country untaxed (Keen & Smith, 2006). After having sold a product inclusive of VAT, a fraudulent importer may disappear without remitting the VAT. The buyer, however, claims an input tax refund and a loss of VAT revenues occurs as a consequence. This fraud not only reduces available public funds, but it also transfers public resources to organized crime (De La Feria, 2020).

Even though MT fraud has emerged as an issue more than 20 years ago (see Cnossen, 2001), there is still considerable uncertainty about the extent of resulting revenue losses. An often-used estimate of revenue losses due to non-compliance is the VAT gap. Defined as the difference between revenues collected and potential revenues, it is regularly calculated for all EU countries, and the total EU VAT gap in the year 2017 is estimated at about 11.2% of potential revenues (Poniatowski, 2019). However, this figure should not be equated with revenue losses from MT fraud (Yiallourou, 2019).Footnote 1 Studies that directly measure VAT fraud come to quite heterogeneous conclusions. Table 1 provides an overview of these estimates. For the EU as a whole, estimates range from annual revenue losses of 0.1% to 9.7% of total VAT revenues. Studies for individual EU countries also differ substantially. While methods vary, estimates are essentially based on trade data or national accounts.

Table 1 Estimates of VAT fraud in Europe

Despite the uncertainty regarding the magnitude of revenue losses, countries have implemented various measures to combat VAT fraud. The key measure used in the EU is to apply the so-called reverse-charge (RC) mechanism on domestic transactions (Keen, 2007). If a good is subject to reverse charge, the tax liability in business-to-business transactions is shifted from the seller to the buyer. Since the seller can no longer charge VAT and disappear without remittance, RC effectively erases the possibility for MT fraud. However, RC removes key features of the common invoice-credit form of the VAT that are important to ensure compliance. In particular, the withholding-tax feature of the VAT is removed and tax collection is effectively shifted to the end of the value chain, which may result in higher tax evasion. As a first step towards an assessment of the costs and benefits of implementing RC, it is important to obtain more reliable estimates of the extent of fraud.

This paper adopts a novel approach to estimate the extent of VAT fraud by analysing the German VAT returns. We argue that the introduction of reverse charge for domestic transactions of certain products has made VAT fraud technically impossible in these areas. The resulting decline in input tax claimed, therefore, reveals the volume of fraudulent trade before RC implementation. Exploiting the German VAT return data at a granular five-digit industry level, we find that VAT reporting, including claims of input VAT, indeed changed significantly after the scope of RC has been widened in the years between 2009 and 2018. We complement our analysis by an analysis of other margins such as total sales and within-EU imports. The estimated effects on these margins are consistent with the view that the effect of RC on VAT returns is driven by MT fraud. Based on our empirical results, we estimate the volume of revenue losses from VAT fraud before introduction of RC at around 5% of total VAT revenues. Assuming that the extent of fraud is similar in the other EU countries, this figure suggests that about half of the VAT gap in the EU is attributable to MT fraud.

Our key contribution to the literature on VAT fraud is to provide a novel approach to quantify the extent of MT fraud. To this end we exploit an institutional change in the VAT liability and utilize tax return data. A related research strategy has been used by Waseem (2019) to analyse VAT evasion and fraud in Pakistan, where illegitimate input tax credits are generated through “invoice mills”. In 2005, a reform reduced the VAT rate to zero for a number of industries, thereby eliminating the tax incentive to misreport. The findings indicate that overclaiming refunds, of which more than a third is found to be due to invoice mills, results in substantial revenue losses. Another contribution of our paper is that we document the scope of RC in German VAT. More specifically, we identify 22 industries affected by RC and quantify the fraction of sales that fall under RC.

We embed the analysis of the effects of the reverse-charge method in a broader discussion of the problem of VAT fraud. In doing so, we explain why RC has been implemented and why it deals effectively with the type of fraud that is so common in Europe. The discussion shows that despite effectiveness of RC in the EU context, there are doubts whether it is really the silver bullet to fight VAT fraud, as it may encourage other forms of non-compliance.

The next section provides a general discussion of VAT fraud and countermeasures, including the reverse-charge mechanism. Section 3 briefly reviews the implementation of reverse charge in Germany. Sections 4 and 5 present the data and discuss the methodology used in the empirical analysis. Section 6 provides the results. Section 7 provides conclusions and suggestions for further research.

2 VAT fraud and countermeasures

The literature on tax evasion has emphasized the great importance of third-party reporting for tax enforcement. The VAT has clear advantages with respect to a retail sales tax in this regard, as taxation of purchases and sales along the value chain creates enforcement spillovers (e.g., Pomeranz, 2015). As firms are entitled to a refund of the taxes paid on their inputs, they have an incentive to request an invoice from their suppliers and report transactions separately from the suppliers to the tax administrator. Hence the common invoice-credit form of the VAT provides a third-party-reported paper trail on taxable transactions. This form of VAT also ensures fractional tax collection along the value chain, and it has an important built-in withholding-tax element: as each supplier withholds VAT paid by the buyer, remittances at upstream stages are protected (Waseem, 2022).

2.1 VAT non-compliance

The third-party reporting and the withholding-tax properties make the VAT particularly attractive as a revenue instrument in weak-enforcement environments. Nevertheless, non-compliance remains a problem for VAT. This is obvious in a business-to-consumer (B2C) setting, as consumers have no incentive to ask for an invoice and may rather buy products and services without VAT. This opens up the room for evasion by the firm and perhaps collusion between firm and customer. Hence, at the end of the value chain the VAT has a “last-mile” problem (Naritomi, 2019). Enforcement issues arise also in a business-to-business (B2B) setting. In particular, the usual invoice-credit method of revenue collection makes the VAT susceptible to fraud. Since a supplier’s invoice constitutes basically “a cheque drawn on the government” (Bird, 1993), there is a strong incentive to seek illegitimate refunds. As Harrison and Krelove (2005) put it, the refunding of credits is the “Achilles heel” of the invoice-credit form of VAT. A swift and easy refunding procedure is important to ensure that the tax does not create any distortions of production, which is regarded as a key advantage compared to gross receipts taxes (e.g., Smart & Bird, 2009). Facing illegitimate claims for VAT refunds, authorities might want to cross-check these claims and the suppliers’ tax payments before processing the requests for refunding. As this will slow down the refunding process, compliance costs will rise and B2B trade may become distorted.

Illegitimate refunds can result from actual purchases of goods and services that are falsely claimed as inputs. In industries that are partially exempt from VAT, such as the financial industry, unjustified refunds may arise by misreporting exempted inputs (Buettner & Erbe, 2014). Illegitimate refunds are obtained also for purchases that did not take place at all or where the seller is not remitting the VAT. Fraudulent firms often act collusively to this end. Harrison and Krelove (2005) and Keen and Smith (2006) report that businesses are set up with the main purpose to generate invoices that can be used for a VAT refund. Empirical evidence by Waseem (2019) documents sizable revenue losses due to those “invoice mills” in Pakistan.

Claiming illegitimate refunds is facilitated in the presence of cross-border trade. One reason is the common practice that exporters do not charge VAT on their sales. As VAT is imposed by the importing country, this practice is consistent with the destination principle, which is the dominant international tax principle guiding the taxation of consumption.Footnote 2 Due to zero-rating of their sales, however, exporters are typically net VAT claimants. While, usually, net VAT claims serve as a warning sign to tax administration, with zero-rating of exports net VAT claims are much more common, which makes it more difficult to identify fraudulent traders (Waseem, 2019). In addition, imports may enter the country untaxed. In this case, non-complying importers would not risk to lose the refund of any import VAT. This is of particular importance in Europe, after the European Union (EU) established the Single Market, which enables free trade of goods and services and has removed border controls between EU member states.Footnote 3 While border controls are important to enforce import VAT and hence to implement taxation according to the destination principle, any “tax frontiers” were considered incompatible with the concept of the Single Market (Martins, 2006).

With the abolition of border controls, import VAT has been replaced in the EU by the “deferred-payment” method (Cnossen & Shoup, 1987). According to this regulation, it is not the exporter but the importer who is liable for VAT. As noted by Cnossen (2001), VAT on imports “is collected on a reverse charge basis: purchasers of out-of-state goods and services declare the imports, [...] apply VAT, and take credit for the same amount, all in the same return”.Footnote 4 The European Commission originally sought a fundamental reform that would have based the EU VAT system on the origin principle and, hence, did away with zero-rating exports altogether. However, what was designed as a “transitional regime” in the early 1990 s (Hart, 1994) is basically still in place today.

Even if the deferred-payment method offers a practical solution to implementing the destination principle in the absence of border controls, the fact that goods and services enter the country untaxed made VAT vulnerable to fraud. In particular, the so-called missing-trader (MT) fraud emerged. In this fraud scheme, the importer charges VAT on a domestic sale, issues an invoice and disappears before remitting any VAT. As the buyer submits the invoice to the authorities, he or she receives an illegitimate refund. As no taxes are paid, this fraud leads to VAT revenue losses.

By exporting and re-importing the goods and in each round not remitting VAT, the fraud can be repeated, which has earned this variant the name “carousel fraud” (e.g., Cnossen, 2001; Keen & Smith, 2006). See Fig. 1 for a schematic illustration. To reduce its traceability, the scheme may also involve “buffer traders,” who buy and resell the goods and might not be aware of trading with fraudsters.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Missing-Trader/Carousel Fraud

2.2 Countermeasures

Apart from proposals to abolish the zero-rating of exports through fundamental VAT reforms (e.g., Keen & Smith, 2000), a number of targeted proposals have been made, and in some cases implemented, that seek to address illegitimate VAT refunding within the current EU VAT system. Usually, VAT is enforced through mandatory VAT reports by registered companies. Based on these reports, firms remit the tax charged on clients (output VAT) net of taxes paid to their suppliers (input VAT). A possible way to limit overclaiming through missing-trader fraud is to supplement the reporting process with the additional requirement to transfer the taxes charged on any transaction into a VAT account (Sinn et al., 2004). Based on individual firms’ accounts, the tax authority can then reconcile the reporting with the actual payments before the input tax is refunded. As Keen and Smith (2006) note, due to higher liquidity requirements, regular transfers to VAT accounts may lead to a substantial increase in compliance costs. Even if institutional or technological arrangements may help limiting the compliance cost (e.g., Ainsworth, 2006), the fear of larger compliance cost may explain why EU countries have not adopted this proposal.Footnote 5

To overcome the zero-rating of exports and the associated break in VAT collection across the value chain, Keen and Smith (1996) developed a concept of a “viable integrated” VAT (VIVAT). Accordingly, exporters would charge a uniform VAT rate on all cross-border B2B transactions within the EU’s Single Market. Importers would be entitled to a refund for these input taxes. As the VIVAT would affect the tax revenue distribution among the EU member states, a clearing mechanism could be added, as envisaged in the EU Commission’s original proposal for a European VAT system, but which could not be agreed upon.

More recently, Ainsworth (2011) proposed automated VAT withholding by the buyer on all transactions. If implemented in all EU member states and equipped with full information exchange, this would enable cross-checking of transactions that cross borders between EU countries in “real time”. Withholding by the buyer, known as reverse withholding, has already been implemented as a tool to improve VAT compliance along the value chain in a number of Latin American and African countries (e.g., Keen & Smith, 2006; Ainsworth, 2011; Yesegat & Joseph, 2017). Under this regulation, the buyer is requested to withhold a part of or all taxes from the gross purchase price of a good or service and immediately remit the withheld amount to the tax administrator. If the seller files for VAT, the withheld amount is credited. This policy reduces the gain of a seller from an informal provision of goods and services (Keen, 2008). Hence, it reduces tax evasion and strengthens the third-party-reported paper trail. Although reverse withholding has been primarily used to close gaps in the VAT paper trail resulting from the informal sector, this measure would also address MT fraud. If the exporting firm (Firm D in Fig. 1) is mandated to withhold part or all of the VAT, the withheld amount would reduce or even eliminate profits from the collusion between fraudsters.

An important advantage of reverse withholding is that this instrument can be applied unilaterally and without the need to adjust the international tax system. In fact, some form of withholding by the buyer has already been used to improve VAT compliance in Europe. Germany, for example, had introduced the so-called deduction mechanism in 1980 for construction services provided by a business registered in another EU country. The recipients of the services needed to withhold the VAT and remit it to the tax collector. If the recipients did not withhold the VAT, they were liable for the VAT (Kurz, 2014). Although this procedure was intended to enforce the destination principle, it was considered to be problematic under EU law because it resulted in unequal treatment of domestic and foreign service providers, discriminating the latter.

To combat VAT fraud, EU member states have been pursuing a different approach. By applying the reverse-charge (RC) mechanism to domestic transactions of certain products or services, they provided for a shift in tax liability from the seller to the buyer.Footnote 6 The buyer offsets the VAT payments on purchases against the refund of the VAT on the inputs. Hence, for products that fall under the RC mechanism, little or no VAT is collected along the value chain and illegitimate refunding due to MT fraud is impossible. At the same time, a discrimination of foreign suppliers is avoided.

RC on domestic trades has been included in the EU VAT directive as a formal instrument of tax policy in 2006.Footnote 7 It should be noted, however, that the introduction of reverse charge to combat VAT fraud is not confined to the EU. Australia introduced RC in 2017 to protect the Goods and Services Tax against MT fraud associated with valuable metals (Evans, 2020). In 2022, South Africa introduced a similar regulation (Botes, 2022).

Similarly to reverse withholding, RC can be implemented unilaterally, but it has clear advantages. In particular, it is based on self-assessment and does not tie up liquidity. Reverse withholding would imply higher compliance costs, as the proper processing of VAT remittances requires time and resources and withholding is associated with high liquidity requirements (Slemrod, 2008). Proper crediting and refunding is also associated with higher administrative cost (Keen & Smith, 2006; Yesegat & Joseph, 2017).

However, RC can be problematic for VAT compliance in general. While RC basically keeps the third-party-reporting feature of the VAT, it gives up on the withholding-tax feature, since compliant suppliers no longer remit VAT. Therefore, while tax fraud through illegitimate refunding will decrease, informal trading of goods and services might increase. Moreover, if a product is subject to RC, little or no VAT is collected along the value chain and tax collection is concentrated on the B2C stage. Accordingly, tax evasion and thus the last-mile problem could intensify (e.g., Keen, 2007; Cnossen, 2009). Moreover, as long as RC is not comprehensive, the fraud can relocate to other goods or other countries (Stiller & Heinemann, 2019). Hence, the advantage that RC prevents illegitimate reimbursement is countered by disadvantages that can be particularly significant in low-enforcement environments.

3 Reverse charge: the case of Germany

As the practice of reverse withholding was considered incompatible with EU law, in 2002, Germany introduced RC, i.e., for certain goods and services VAT liability was shifted to the buyer.Footnote 8 Since then, the German VAT Act has been modified several times and the list of goods and services affected by reverse charge has been expanded over time. The main amendments to the VAT Act are reported in Table 2.Footnote 9

Initially, RC was applied mainly to cross-border services in the construction sector. Previously, in this industry, foreign suppliers had to charge VAT, which was refundable as input tax for their domestic business clients. As VAT enforcement of remittances by foreign suppliers proved difficult, reverse withholding was introduced. This regulation required the domestic firm to withhold the VAT invoiced by the foreign supplier. In 2002, withholding was replaced by RC, and the tax liability was shifted to the domestic client (Kurz, 2014). Since the introduction of RC in the construction industry substituted reverse withholding, no effects on VAT fraud are expected for these services. The other two types of transactions subjected to RC in 2002, barter-like and real-estate transactions, were not subjected to the deduction method before. Introducing RC in these areas aimed to secure VAT revenues on those transactions.

Subsequently, the RC mechanism was extended to other products and services, where VAT enforcement proved difficult or fraud connected with cross-border transactions emerged. The first extension in 2004 addressed specific settings of construction work, where subcontractors are involved and was motivated by VAT fraud. The second extension in 2005 involved the supply of energy and gas. This regulation followed an EU directive that defines the place of service delivery for tax purposes for this type of services (Vellen, 2005). Neither the EU directive nor the German law referred to VAT fraud in the legislative explanatory memorandum.

The following extensions of RC on domestic transactions have all been introduced to combat VAT fraud (Pahne, 2011). In 2010, RC has been extended to trade with certificates under the EU emission trading system, after major cases of MT fraud were detected.Footnote 10 In January 2011, RC was introduced in the trade of scrap material, gold, and for cleaning services. In July 2011 a new regulation was introduced assigning trades regarding mobile phones and integrated circuits to RC. The 2013 amendment extended the 2005 regulation to energy services. Even though the earlier regulation was not motivated by VAT fraud, this extension aimed at preventing VAT fraud in electricity and gas markets (Meurer, 2013). In 2014, another extension was implemented to address fraud related to trade in tablets, games consoles, laptops, and metals. Since the empirical analysis below looks at the evolution of VAT between 2009 and 2018, the focus is on the more recent RC expansions, all of which are related to VAT fraud.

Table 2 Introduction of reverse charge in Germany 2002–2018.

4 Data

To analyse the effects of the introduction of reverse charge, we use administrative data from the German VAT returns (Umsatzsteuer-Voranmeldungen). The data covers the period between 2009 and 2018 on an annual basis and is derived by aggregation of all VAT returns at industry level.Footnote 11 The underlying VAT returns refer to the universe of German and foreign firms that file these tax returns in Germany. These are all firms whose taxable supplies and services have a yearly value greater than 17,500 € (about 3,300,000 firms).Footnote 12 Reporting is mandatory and is the main procedure to claim input tax payments.

Table 3 Descriptive statistics

The data contains information about firms’ VAT remittances and claims of input VAT. In the returns, firms report the VAT base (total domestic sales) and the VAT liability on different types of transactions including imports from other EU countries (EU imports) and exports to other EU countries (EU exports).Footnote 13 In our analysis, we focus on input VAT, as it is directly related to MT fraud. In addition, we consider effects on total domestic sales as well as on EU imports and EU exports as these transactions are linked to MT fraud either via forward or backward linkages or are used for concealment.

The unit of observation in our analysis is the 5-digit NACE classification (Revision 2, 2008), i.e., the most granular level of industry classification comprising 778 industries. A key advantage of the dataset is that it offers comprehensive information about all firms registered for VAT. Moreover, it directly reflects the reporting items in the underlying VAT returns, which enables us to gain a comprehensive overview of VAT reporting and the effects of reverse charge.Footnote 14

Table 3 shows the descriptive statistics of the variables in constant prices of 2018. The value of domestic sales is about 6.2 billion € per industry-year. EU exports amount to 0.8 billion €. German industries are generally net EU exporters, as EU exports exceed EU imports. We observe on average 4,250 firms per industry.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Fraction of Sales Subject to RC: Non-/Affected Industries

Notes: Sales subject to RC relative to all domestic sales. Averaged across the respective industry group. Years covered: 2009 to 2018. In prices of 2018. We identify 22 individual industries whose main business activity is related to products newly covered by RC in the period studied, i.e., in the years between 2009 and 2018.Footnote 15 Panel B shows the descriptive statistics for these 22 industries and Panel C refers to the remaining industries. Interestingly, trade intensity is higher for industries covered by RC as compared to other industries, and EU imports exceed exports.

Figure 2 shows the development of RC sales relative to all domestic sales in the two groups of industries. Note that the fraction of sales subject to reverse charge in the industries affected by RC is sizeable but much below 100%. This reflects the fact that the industries are aggregates capturing sales of a whole range of products, only part of which fall under reverse charge. Moreover, reverse charge does not apply to sales to final consumers. However, the increase in RC sales is clearly concentrated among these industries affected by RC. The strong difference with regard to other industries confirms our identification of industries subject to RC.

5 Methodology

In our empirical analysis, we explore the effects of the implementation of reverse charge (RC) on VAT returns. The database reports the actual VAT returns at the level of individual industries. To remove industry-level effects and common trends, we explore the effect of RC on input VAT using industry-level panel regressions. Denoting observations by industry i and year t, if certain assumptions are met, an estimate of the treatment effect can be obtained by regressing the outcome on the volume of sales subject to RC, as follows.

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta \log y_{i,t} = \alpha _i + \delta _t + \beta \log RC_{i,t} + \gamma \log y_{i,t-1} + u_{i,t}, \end{aligned}$$
(1)

where \(\alpha _i\) is an industry-level fixed effect, \(\delta\) captures period-specific effects, and \(u_{i,t}\) is an error term. In the basic specification, \(\Delta y_{i,t}\) denotes the changes of total input VAT of industry i at time t in logs as a measure of innovations in claims of input VAT. The inclusion of \(y_{i,t-1}\) captures the adjustment process. The key explanatory variable is \(RC_{i,t}\), the (log) volume of sales subject to RC in the same industry. This variable reflects the extent to which the tax liability is shifted onto the buyer.

\(\beta\) reveals the average treatment effect of RC on the treated industries. If all transactions in an industry are carried out by compliant traders, the level of RC sales in an industry should not affect total input VAT. In this case, \(\beta\) would be zero. If, however, some of the trading is fraudulent, we expect that the introduction of RC causes a decline in input VAT (\(\beta <0\)). In fact, since there is no refunding of input VAT and, hence, no opportunity for fraud, there should be a decrease in input taxes in an amount equal to the previous revenue losses due to VAT fraud. \(\gamma\) can be interpreted as the speed of adjustment to the introduction of reverse charge. If \(\gamma =-1\), the effect of reverse charge is fully and instantaneously reflected in the level of the dependent variable. But if \(-1<\gamma <0,\) there is lagged adjustment and \(\beta\) captures only the first-period effect.Footnote 16

The variation in sales subject to RC has different sources. Institutional variation comes from the gradual increase of the number of products and services subject to RC. However, the variation also reflects changes in the volume of trades for other reasons, for instance, changes in the demand for products. Those changes may well be positively correlated with the error term \(u_{i,t}.\) This raises concerns that the estimate of the treatment effect is biased. To overcome this problem, we employ an instrumental variable (IV) approach based on the extension of the scope of RC in Germany. More precisely, we use a binary indicator that indicates whether the products of the given industry are subject to reverse charge in the given year, or not. Thus, in order to identify the effect of RC implementation, we rely only on the variation of the tax law.

Note that the IV approach is implemented in a panel regression that includes industry fixed effects. Hence, time-invariant differences between industries, which matter for the potential gains and risks of MT fraud, are controlled for. This is important, since RC is implemented in industries that are particularly vulnerable to MT fraud. Including industry-level fixed effects ensures that the estimate of \(\beta\) is not subject to a selection bias.

A requirement for using the RC implementation as an instrumental variable for actual RC sales is that the exclusion restriction holds. This is ensured by the fact that the introduction of RC in an industry affects firms only to the extent that the responsibility for remittances is transferred to the buyer. There is no separate effect of the policy, especially since the basic tax liability remains unchanged. Even if RC leads to a reduction in compliance costs because the liquidity requirement is lower as there are no VAT payments and reimbursements, this reduction in compliance costs depends on the volume of sales that are subject to RC. Another requirement is that the instrumental variable has sufficient predicting power, an issue that requires us to explore the first-stage regressions.

Since MT fraud aims to obtain illegitimate tax refunds for input taxes, we first examine the effects on input taxes using the above regression. To corroborate the presumption of MT fraud and shed more light on the process, we also consider alternative outcome variables.

Effects on domestic sales are expected, since, in order to conceal MT fraud, fraudulent trade is often embedded in other transactions (i.e., buffer transactions).Footnote 17 In particular, we expect total domestic sales to decline with the introduction of reverse charge. A decline of reported domestic sales could also be caused by an expansion of tax evasion. As discussed above, a side effect of reverse charge could be that products are sold informally rather than formally at the end of the value chain, without remittance of VAT. This would further contribute to a decline in reported sales. However, it is not clear how much of an impact this has in our study design. While the reverse-charge method is implemented at the level of individual goods, our analysis is based on data for industries. We compare industries where the sale of these goods accounts for a larger share of the business activity with industries where the share is small, and the industries identified as treated in this way are predominantly less active in retailing.

Systematic MT fraud may also affect EU imports. This follows, since missing traders exploit the fact that EU imports are not subject to import VAT. As we noted above, since they do not receive a VAT refund anyway, it is particularly attractive for firms to disappear without remitting the VAT collected on a resale of products imported from another EU country. In other words, the withholding-tax property of VAT (Waseem, 2022) is absent for EU imports. Hence, if MT fraud is significant, the introduction of RC may not only lead to a decrease in input VAT but also of EU imports that are an essential part of MT fraud. Whether this is reflected in the VAT statistics is not clear, however, because if fraudulent traders disappear, the question is whether imports were reported nonetheless.Footnote 18

Similarly, MT fraud can be organized as carousel fraud, where goods are exported into another EU country after achieving a fraudulent input tax rebate. Hence, also EU exports may decline in an industry, where RC has been implemented, effectively stopping carousel fraud.

6 Results

6.1 Basic regression results

Table 4 provides the results for input VAT. The first specification, reported in column (1), shows panel estimates with a full set of industry- and year-fixed effects. The results indicate a positive effect of sales subject to RC (RC sales) on reported input taxes. However, as noted above, the sales may be correlated with the input taxes. Therefore, an instrument-variable (IV) approach is preferable, which employs a binary indicator reflecting the introduction of RC in the treated industries.

Column (2) shows the results of the corresponding IV specification. The first-stage F-statistic reported at the lower panel of the table clearly supports the predictive power of the instrumental variable.Footnote 19 With regard to the effect of RC sales on the input VAT, the specification shows a significant negative effect. The point estimate indicates that an increase of the volume of sales subject to RC by 100 log points is associated with a decline in input VAT by 2.9 log points.

Since the dependent variable reflects the development of input VAT at industry level, it is likely that the effect of RC partly captures the general development of industrial activity. Therefore, in column (3) we introduce as control variable the change of the total number of reporting firms. While the effect of the RC indicator is confirmed, we find a strong positive effect of the number of reporting firms indicating that the growth of input taxes is closely related to the growth of the number of firms in the respective industry.Footnote 20

Table 4 RC effect on input VAT
Table 5 RC effects domestic sales

The results of the IV specifications indicate that less input tax is claimed under RC. Before conducting robustness checks and evaluating the empirical magnitudes of MT fraud, we first want to check whether similar effects can be found for other variables in the VAT statistics.

Table 5 reports results with the change in (log) domestic sales as outcome variable. Note that even if a firm’s products are subject to RC, the sales of the firm would still be taxable. What changes is simply who is liable for the VAT. As compliance costs decrease rather than increase along the value chain, for compliant traders there should be no negative effect from the introduction of RC. But if MT fraud is organized with the involvement of buffer traders, the introduction of RC would lead to a decline of total sales, i.e., due to a reduction in buffer trade.

Similarly to the results for input VAT, the fixed-effect estimates in column (1) suggest that the volume of sales subject to RC has a positive effect on domestic sales. However, the results of the preferred instrumental variable regressions, reported in columns (2) and (3), point to a decline in domestic sales related to the introduction of reverse charge.

Table 6 RC effect on EU imports

A side effect of reverse charge could be that products are sold informally rather than formally at the end of the value chain, without remittance of the VAT. The decline of domestic sales may, therefore, also pick up an increase in VAT evasion. But, even if the decline of domestic sales reflects an increase of VAT evasion, it is not clear whether this affects input VAT.Footnote 21 Since no VAT is collected along the value chain under reverse charge, products can be sold “under the desk” without the necessity to underreport inputs.

Table 6 reports results for imports from other EU countries, with the change in (log) EU imports as outcome variable. While column (1) indicates that the volume of sales subject to RC has a positive effect on EU imports, the instrumental variable regressions in columns (2) and (3) point to a decline in imports. Though the effects are estimated imprecisely, the point estimates indicate a similar decline to the one found for input VAT and domestic sales.

The finding that the point estimates for input VAT, domestic sales and EU imports are similar is consistent with a decrease in MT fraud being the primary cause of the decline in input VAT, because, if MT fraud is no longer profitable under RC, the decline of input VAT is reflected in a decline of associated buffer trades and EU imports.

Table 7 RC effect on EU exports

If fraud is in the form of carousel fraud and goods cross the borders several times, there might also be effects on EU exports. Table 7 shows the effects on EU exports. Column (1) reports results of the fixed-effect regression, where the volume of sales subject to RC exerts a small positive effect on EU exports. The instrumental variable regressions in columns (2) and (3) also point to a positive impact of RC on exports. While this result does not support the presence of carousel fraud, it should be noted that a decline will only be found if EU exports associated with VAT fraud were reported before the introduction of RC.

6.2 Robustness checks and alternative specifications

As a robustness check against different time trends across groups of industries, we report results from a set of regressions in which we include (one-digit) industry-year fixed effects. This specification is also useful to rule out the effects of general, non-specific measures to combat VAT non-compliance, if those affect industry groups differently.Footnote 22

Table 8 reports results for our preferred specification, i.e., a fixed-effects instrumental variable estimation. For the four outcome variables, the results are qualitatively identical to the finding from the basic specifications. This suggests that trends for groups of industries do not affect our basic results, although the effects of RC are not precisely estimated.

Table 8 Robustness: industry-year effects

To address the concern that non-affected industries might not be sufficiently comparable to industries subject to RC, we conduct regressions where we include only those industries in the control group that may have a similar exposure to MT fraud. To this end, we focus on industries with similar trade intensity (i.e., exports relative to domestic sales, in 2018). In this robustness check, trade intensity serves as a proxy for how easily an industry’s output can be shipped across borders, and, hence, how easy it might be to engage in MT or carousel fraud. Table 9 shows the results with the so-defined set of non-affected industries. While the set of treated industries is the same, the estimation sample includes 273 instead of 756 industries in the control group. The empirical results for input taxes and domestic sales are similar to the basic specifications, suggesting that the validity of the above findings is not limited by a lack of comparability between treated and control groups. Interestingly, the results get stronger rather than weaker, and even the expected negative effects on EU trade prove significant.

Table 9 Robustness: industries with similar trade intensity

If the measured effects are driven by a decline in VAT fraud, as we suspect, we will also expect a decline in the number of firms in the VAT statistics. To examine whether RC introduction is associated with firm exit, we regress the change in the number of taxable firms on sales subject to RC. The results are shown in Table 10. The instrumental-variable results in column (2) show that an increase in RC sales is in fact related to a decline in the number of taxable firms. This finding supports the view that registered firms participating in MT fraud have disappeared. This could explain why the treatment effect in the basic specification is slightly smaller when controlling for the number of firms. Accordingly, it seems reasonable to use the results of the basic specification without controlling for the change in the number of firms for the calculation of the total VAT revenue effects of RC.

Table 10 RC effect on the (log) number of registered firms

6.3 Magnitude of MT fraud

In order to provide a rough estimate of the magnitude of MT fraud and the associated revenue loss, we finally evaluate the basic findings of the effect of RC on input taxes. The preferred estimate of the slope parameter in column (2) of Table 4 shows that, when RC sales increase by one log point, the input tax declines by 0.029 log points. Since the above results indicate that there is lagged adjustment, the long-run effect is bigger in absolute terms pointing to a decline by 0.101 log points.Footnote 23 From the first-stage regression, we know that after introduction of RC, sales subject to RC have increased substantially in treated industries. The point estimate indicates an increase by 195 log points.Footnote 24 Based on this figure, input taxes should have declined by 19.8 log points. The average value of input tax payments in the industries affected by RC is 2.2 bill. euros. Using this figure to evaluate the treatment effect, the decline in input taxes is estimated with 395 mill. euros per industry. For all treated industries, the effect amounts to 8.682 bill. euros. As the decline results primarily from the fact that MT fraud is no longer possible under RC, this figure indicates the damage to VAT revenues caused by this fraud. If this value is put in relation to total tax revenues, the revenue loss due to MT fraud in Germany amounts to around 5.4% of German VAT revenues.Footnote 25 As the VAT gap in Germany is estimated at about 10% in 2009 (Barbone et al., 2013), i.e., in the first year of our period of investigation, this suggests that about half of the VAT gap is attributable to MT fraud.

7 Summary and concluding remarks

This paper sheds light on VAT fraud through illegitimate input tax credits, that has plagued the countries of the European Union, in particular after the creation of the common market and the removal of border controls. As the quantification of the magnitude of VAT fraud has proved difficult, this paper adopts a new method to estimate the extent of this fraud by exploring German VAT data.

The introduction of the reverse-charge method for domestic transactions of certain products has made VAT fraud technically impossible for these products. The resulting decline in input taxes claimed, therefore, reveals the volume of fraudulent trade before the policy implementation. Exploiting the German VAT return data at industry level, we find that VAT reporting changed indeed and that claims of input VAT declined substantially after the scope of RC has been widened in the years between 2009 and 2018. We complement our analysis by examining other margins such as total sales and within-EU imports. The estimated effects on these margins are consistent with the view that the effect of RC on VAT returns is driven by what is referred to as MT fraud.

Based on our finding of a significant decline of input VAT, we estimate that the volume of MT fraud stopped by RC in the years between 2009 and 2018 amounts to about 5% of VAT revenues. This confirms concerns of considerable revenue losses due to fraud: for Germany, our estimate adds up to losses of around 8-9 billion euros per year. Compared with the range of previous studies, which largely use indirect methods and exploit other data sources, such as trade statistics or national accounts, this estimated value is around the midpoint of the range of estimates. While our estimate is lower than the existing estimate of the revenue loss in Germany, it should be noted that our estimate only relates to industries where the government has put a stop to MT fraud by introducing reverse charge. It cannot be ruled out that there are other industries in which MT fraud continues to be practiced.

To what extent the findings from Germany can be generalized to other countries is not clear, however. It is conceivable that decentralized tax collection at subnational level increases Germany’s exposure to VAT fraud and that the problem of VAT fraud is less pronounced in other countries with more centralized tax administration.

Even though our study shows significant revenue losses due to VAT fraud, the question remains as to whether RC is the best instrument to address this issue. While a comprehensive evaluation of the reverse-charge method is clearly beyond the scope of this paper, our analysis provides guidance on how to examine the impact of the introduction of the RC method based on VAT statistics.

Our discussion has shown that the protection of tax revenues is only one element of a proper cost-benefit assessment. Another issue is the effect on compliance cost. Leaving aside the one-time costs of adjustment to RC, while firms still have to file VAT returns under RC, a decline in compliance cost may occur because the liquidity requirement is lower as there are no VAT remittances in business-to-business (B2B) trade. However, the consequences of reverse charge for VAT compliance need to be discussed more broadly. Since VAT is no longer collected along the value chain, the tax collection is effectively shifted to the end of the value chain. The VAT is known to have a last-mile problem that is likely to be exacerbated if the reverse-charge method is applied to domestic trade. Accordingly, tax evasion in business-to-consumer (B2C) transactions could increase. In addition to this argument, due to the lack of VAT withholding, also the informal sector may increase.

It should also be noted that once reverse charge is implemented in one area, fraud might spread to other areas. This could lead to a process in which more and more areas need to be subjected to reverse charge. In fact, as our discussion shows, the European problem of VAT fraud has become so virulent not least because Europe switched to the deferred-payment method in the first place, which involves a reverse-charge system for intra-European cross-border trade. Through this arrangement, the withholding-tax feature of the VAT is not effective for imports and the goods and services basically enter the respective member country untaxed. This fuels the potential profits of MT fraud, where VAT is charged by the importer but not remitted.

To some extent, the potential proliferation of the reverse-charge mechanism is also reflected in the policy debate. While the current EU directive restricts member states to subject only specific products to RC, proposals for a broader application are under discussion. One proposal is to allow EU countries to switch entirely for all domestic B2B trade to the RC method. However, if RC were applied generally, VAT is effectively transformed into a retail sales tax (De La Feria, 2019). The fractional tax collection along the value chain and the withholding-tax property of VAT would completely disappear. Though compliant firms would still report taxable sales, the quality of the reporting can be questioned, as no taxes are collected on B2B transactions.