Skip to main content
Log in

A New Approach to Measure Italian Regional Trade Flows with Administrative Micro Firm-Level Data

  • Research paper
  • Published:
Italian Economic Journal Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper, we present a novel approach to measure domestic bilateral trade flows in intermediate and final consumption in the Italian regions. We reconstruct regional trade flows in final consumption by using administrative data from tax returns that limit the issues of survey-based measures. We also investigate the main determinants of domestic regional trade flows in Italy by adopting a spatial gravity modeling framework that allows for the inclusion of multiple spatial dependence effects. Moreover, we provide evidence of the presence of geographical heterogeneity and a specific focus on trade flows in the manufacturing sector. Our findings, which are robust to alternative specifications, suggest that the introduction of different sources of spatial dependence is relevant to understand the occurrence of multiple types of network effects when considering origin, destination, and origin–destination linkages in trade flows. We also document regional differences in the spatial concentration of trade flows in intermediate and final consumption. Finally, we discuss the main implications and future avenues of inquiry of our research.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Data Availability

The participants of this study did not give written consent for their data to be shared publicly, so due to the sensitive nature of the research supporting data is not available.

Notes

  1. In the trade literature, multilateral resistance terms are defined as the trade barriers across all trading partners that can influence bilateral trade flows (Anderson and Van Wincoop 2003). For critical discussions, see Yotov et al. (2016).

  2. In this paper, we consider the two autonomous provinces of Trento and Bolzano, which are counted separately in the NUTS-2 regional classification, as a single region labeled Trentino Alto-Adige, to be consistent with the Italian regional framework.

  3. For the list of Italian NUTS-2 regions, Nace Rev.2 sectors, statistical classification of CPA, and commodity labeling, see the Appendix.

  4. It is outside the boundaries of the present work to provide a full description of the existing literature. For a review of spatial interaction models, see Thomas-Agnan and LeSage (2021); for a review of regional trade flows, see Yotov (2022).

  5. For more details on the economic background of SAR gravity models, see Fischer and Griffith (2008).

  6. Cipollina et al. (2016), for instance, decompose multilateral resistance barriers in three components: bilateral trade barriers; the origin region’s resistance to trade with all other regions; and, the destination region’s resistance to trade with all other regions.

  7. In the Appendix, to save space, we provide further details on the passages included in our methodological approach.

  8. Data are extracted from the MEF VAT database VT-form for the fiscal year 2016 covering more than 4,1 million taxpayers subject to VAT (about 84 percent of total VAT declarations) and about 2,1 billion euro VAT transactions; for more details, see Cirillo et al. (2021).

  9. The relation in Equation (1) is the spatial SAR extension of the standard log-linearised gravity equation model, as discussed in LeSage and Pace (2008a).

  10. Note that, \(\otimes \) is the Kronecker product that allows obtaining vectors without having to deal directly with \(n^2 \times n^2\) matrices improving computational efficiency; for a more detailed discussion see LeSage and Thomas-Agnan (2015).

  11. In detail, the parameter \(\theta \) is applied to \(Y'_{IC}\) in commodity terms, by assuming, without loss of generality, that each sector produces its typical commodity; in our data, for instance, the agriculture sector produces 97% of agricultural goods. In the Appendix, to save space, we report results regarding C and \(\theta \).

  12. The vector \(Y'_{IC}\) is rearranged in I matrices of \(n \times n\) dimension (i.e., one for each commodity i) in order to be consistent with national account aggregates. Such matrices are subsequently balanced by using a share approach: intermediate consumption (IC) shares are calculated, for each commodity i, as the ratio between the ‘corrected inter-regional IC flows of region o towards all other regions’ on the ‘total amount of region o’s intermediate consumption for all commodities’. Finally, the shares are applied to the net regionalised aggregate data on intermediate consumption, that is, net to imports linked to intermediate commodities.

  13. Location quotients are obtained as the product between the ratio of regional employment of sector s and national employment of sector s, and the ratio between national total employment and regional total employment for origin o and destination d regions, respectively (Flegg et al. 1995).

  14. Data on regional exports are from the ISTAT-ICE yearbook for the year 2016.

  15. Data on output are from the ISTAT Input-Output table supply table at purchasers’ prices, year 2016.

  16. Data on regional employment are from the ISTAT national accounts regional main aggregates, year 2016.

  17. In our data, zero trade flows among Italian regions for all sectors are of limited importance, counting for about 1% of total observations, and mostly related to trade flows among small regions, with respect to other sources of data like the ISTAT road transport regional matrix. As for the explanatory variables that we build by using location quotients, initially, there can be some negative values due to small regions and particular sectors, which derive from the calculation of each variable. Negative values are corrected given the logarithmic specification in the spatial gravity framework. For more details on the treatment of zero trade flows in applied works, see Anderson and Van Wincoop (2004).

  18. The optimal bandwidth of the GWR has been selected from the optimal minimization of the cross-validation criterion that maximizes the model’s predictive power (Harris et al. 2011). Model diagnostics and the results (p-value) of the spatial non-stationarity tests for each variable (Brunsdon et al. 1998) are reported at the bottom of Table 6.

  19. The usage of alternative spatial econometric models, such as the SEM and the SARAR, does not significantly modify our main findings; results are available upon request.

  20. IRAP database from Department of Finance-MEF.

  21. ISTAT - Input–Output table, 2016, supply table at purchasers’ prices.

  22. ISTAT - National Accounting Matrix, 2014.

  23. ISTAT - Input–Output table, 2016, supply table at purchasers’ prices.

  24. ISTAT - Regional account, 2016.

  25. ISTAT-ICE yearbook "Commercio estero e attivita’ internazionali delle imprese", ed 2017, data 2016. The imports are then split in \(Import_{d,i}^{HH}\) and \(Import_{d,i}^{IC}\) based on the weight of import for household final consumption and import for intermediate consumption, respectively, on the aggregate demand.

  26. National accounts regional main aggregates: Final consumption expenditure of households by expenditure item (Coicop 2 digit) and durability, 2016.

References

  • Agnosteva DE, Anderson JE, Yotov YV (2019) Intra-national trade costs: Assaying regional frictions. Eur Econ Rev 112:32–50

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson JE, Van Wincoop E (2003) Gravity with gravitas: a solution to the border puzzle. Am Econ Rev 93(1):170–192

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson JE, Van Wincoop E (2004) Trade costs. J Econ Lit 42(3):691–751

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson JE, Borchert I, Mattoo A, Yotov YV (2018) Dark costs, missing data: Shedding some light on services trade. Eur Econ Rev 105:193–214

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anselin L, Bera AK, Florax R, Yoon MJ (1996) Simple diagnostic tests for spatial dependence. Reg Sci Urban Econ 26(1):77–104

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arbia G (2016) Spatial econometrics: a broad view. Foundations and Trends® in Econometrics 8(3–4):145–265

  • Arkolakis C, Huneeus F, Miyauchi Y (2023) Spatial production networks. Tech. rep, National Bureau of Economic Research

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ascani A, Bettarelli L, Resmini L, Balland PA (2020) Global networks, local specialisation and regional patterns of innovation. Res Policy 49(8):104031

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baldassarre A, Calà VF, Carullo D, Dudu H, Fusco E, Giacobbe P, Orecchia C (2023) Simulating the effect of business tax abolition through a new regional cge model: Evidence from italy

  • Basile R, Ciccarelli C (2018) The location of the italian manufacturing industry, 1871–1911: a sectoral analysis. Journal of Economic Geography 18(3):627–661

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Basile R, de Nardis S, Pappalardo C (2014) Firm heterogeneity and regional business cycles differentials. Journal of Economic Geography 14(6):1087–1115

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Basile R, Commendatore P, De Benedictis L, Kubin I (2016) An investigation of interregional trade network structures. Springer, pp 123–172

  • Basile R, Commendatore P, De Benedictis L, Kubin I (2018) The impact of trade costs on the european regional trade network: an empirical and theoretical analysis. Rev Int Econ 26(3):578–609

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Behrens K, Ertur C, Koch W (2012) ‘dua’gravity: Using spatial econometrics to control for multilateral resistance. J Appl Economet 27(5):773–794

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bentivogli C, Ferraresi T, Monti P, Panicciá R, Rosignoli S (2019) Italian regions in global value chains: An input-output approach. Politica economica 1:55–94

    Google Scholar 

  • Bergstrand J, Egger P (2010) A general equilibrium theory for estimating gravity equations of bilateral fdi, final goods trade and intermediate goods trade. The Gravity Model in International Trade: Advances and Applications, Cambridge University Press, New York pp 29–70

  • Bolea L, Duarte R, Hewings GJ, Jiménez S, Sánchez-Chóliz J (2022) The role of regions in global value chains: an analysis for the european union. Papers in Regional Science

  • Borchert I, Larch M, Shikher S, Yotov YV (2021) The international trade and production database for estimation (itpd-e). International Economics 166:140–166

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boschma R, Iammarino S (2009) Related variety, trade linkages, and regional growth in italy. Econ Geogr 85(3):289–311

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brandsma A, Kancs d, Monfort P, Rillaers A, (2015) Rhomolo: A dynamic spatial general equilibrium model for assessing the impact of cohesion policy. Papers in Regional Science 94:S197–S221

  • Brunsdon C, Fotheringham AS, Charlton ME (1996) Geographically weighted regression: A method for exploring spatial nonstationarity. Geogr Anal 28(4):281–298

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brunsdon C, Fotheringham A, MCharlton, (1998) Spatial nonstationarity and autoregressive models. Environment and Planning A: Economy and Space 30(6):957–973

  • Brunsdon C, Fotheringham A, Charlton M (1999) Some notes on parametric significance tests for geographically weighted regression. J Reg Sci 39(3):497–524

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cai M (2022) A calibrated gravity model of interregional trade. Spatial Economic Analysis pp 1–19

  • Cainelli G, Iacobucci D (2012) Agglomeration, related variety, and vertical integration. Econ Geogr 88(3):255–277

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cainelli G, Ganau R, Modica M (2019) Industrial relatedness and regional resilience in the european union. Pap Reg Sci 98(2):755–778

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Capello R (2019) Regional development theories and formalised economic approaches: An evolving relationship. Italian Economic Journal 5:1–16

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Casarico A, Lattanzio S (2022) The heterogeneous effects of covid-19 on labor market flows: Evidence from administrative data. The Journal of Economic Inequality 20(3):537–558

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Celi G, Segnana ML (2000) Trade and labour markets: vertical and regional differentiation in italy. Labour 14(3):441–472

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cerqua A, Pellegrini G (2020) Local multipliers at work. Ind Corp Chang 29(4):959–977

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christie E (2003) Potential trade in south-east europe: a gravity model approach. SEER: Journal for Labour and Social Affairs in Eastern Europe 5(4):81–101

  • Cipollina MP, De Benedictis L, Salvatici L, Vicarelli C (2016) Policy measurement and multilateral resistance in gravity models

  • Cirillo C, Imperioli L, Manzo M (2021) Investigating the incidence of value added tax on households income: New evidence from italy. International Journal of Microsimulation 14(3):85–118

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Comber A, Brunsdon C, Charlton M, Dong G, Harris R, Lu B, Lü Y, Murakami D, Nakaya T, Wang Y et al (2023) A route map for successful applications of geographically weighted regression. Geogr Anal 55(1):155–178

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corrado L, Fingleton B (2012) Where is the economics in spatial econometrics? J Reg Sci 52(2):210–239

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coşar AK, Demir B, Ghose D, Young N (2022) Road capacity, domestic trade and regional outcomes. Journal of Economic Geography 22(5):901–929

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Costa S, Sallusti F, Vicarelli C, Zurlo D (2022) From micro to macro: Micro-foundations of the italian business cycle co-movements during the crises. Italian Economic Journal 8(3):499–522

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Costantino S, Cracolici MF, Elhorst JP (2023) A spatial gravity model approach for the analysis of local tourism demand in italy. Papers in Regional Science

  • Cuñat A, Zymek R (2022) The (structural) gravity of epidemics. Eur Econ Rev 144:104082

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis JC, Holly BP (2006) Regional analysis using census bureau microdata at the center for economic studies. Int Reg Sci Rev 29(3):278–296

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Lombaerde P, Iapadre L, McCranie A, Tajoli L (2018) Using network analysis to study globalization, regionalization, and multi-polarity-introduction to special section. Network Science 6(4):494–516

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Di Berardino C, Onesti G (2021) I processi di integrazione tra manifattura e servizi. un’indagine sulle regioni italiane. Rivista economica del Mezzogiorno 35(1):195–224

  • Di Caro P (2015) Recessions, recoveries and regional resilience: evidence on italy. Camb J Reg Econ Soc 8(2):273–291

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Di Caro P (2017) Testing and explaining economic resilience with an application to italian regions. Pap Reg Sci 96(1):93–113

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Di Caro P, Fratesi U (2019) Investigating the spatial patterns of regional fiscal residua in italy. Politica economica 35(3):367–394

    Google Scholar 

  • Di Caro P, Sacchi A (2020) The heterogeneous effects of labor informality on vat revenues: Evidence on a developed country. J Macroecon 63:103190

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Di Pietro F, Lecca P, Salotti S (2021) Regional economic resilience in the european union: a numerical general equilibrium analysis. Spat Econ Anal 16(3):287–312

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dijkstra L, Garcilazo E, McCann P (2015) The effects of the global financial crisis on european regions and cities. Journal of Economic Geography 15(5):935–949

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diodato D, Weterings AB (2015) The resilience of regional labour markets to economic shocks: Exploring the role of interactions among firms and workers. Journal of economic geography 15(4):723–742

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Egger P, Pfaffermayr M (2016) A generalized spatial error components model for gravity equations. Empirical Economics 50:177–195

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Egger P, Larch M, Nigai S, Yotov Y (2021) Trade costs in the global economy: Measurement, aggregation and decomposition. Tech. rep., WTO Staff Working Paper

  • Egger PH, Staub KE (2015) Controlling for multilateral resistance terms in linearized trade gravity equations without spatial econometrics. Available at SSRN https://ssrncom/abstract=2737669

  • Fischer MM, Griffith DA (2008) Modeling spatial autocorrelation in spatial interaction data: an application to patent citation data in the european union. J Reg Sci 48(5):969–989

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flegg AT, Tohmo T (2013) Regional input-output tables and the flq formula: a case study of finland. Reg Stud 47(5):703–721

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flegg AT, Webber C, Elliott M (1995) On the appropriate use of location quotients in generating regional input-output tables. Reg Stud 29(6):547–561

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fotheringham A, Brunsdon C, Charlton M (2002) Geographically Weighted Regression: The Analysis of Spatially Varying Relationships. Wiley, https://books.google.it/books?id=GFjFX-3dH68C

  • Franco-Bedoya S, Frohm E (2022) Reduced ‘border effects’, free trade agreements and international trade. The World Economy 45(4):1112–1139

  • Geniaux G, Martinetti D (2018) A new method for dealing simultaneously with spatial autocorrelation and spatial heterogeneity in regression models. Regional Science and Urban Economics 72(C):74–85

  • Greaney TM, Kiyota K (2020) The gravity model and trade in intermediate inputs. The World Economy 43(8):2034–2049

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrington JW, MacPherson AD, Lombard JR (1991) Interregional trade in producer services: Review and synthesis. Growth Chang 22(4):75–94

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harris P, Brunsdon C, Fotheringham aS, (2011) Links, comparisons and extensions of the geographically weighted regression model when used as a spatial predictor. Stochastic Environmental Research and Risk Assessment 25(2):123–138

  • Head K, Mayer T (2014) Gravity equations: Workhorse, toolkit, and cookbook. In: Handbook of international economics, vol 4, Elsevier, pp 131–195

  • Helpman E, Melitz M, Rubinstein Y (2008) Estimating trade flows: Trading partners and trading volumes. Q J Econ 123(2):441–487

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kelejian HH, Prucha IR (2010) Specification and estimation of spatial autoregressive models with autoregressive and heteroskedastic disturbances. Journal of Econometrics 157(1):53–67, nonlinear and Nonparametric Methods in Econometrics

  • Koch W, LeSage JP (2015) Latent multilateral trade resistance indices: Theory and evidence. Scottish Journal of Political Economy 62(3):264–290

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lahr ML, Ferreira JP, Többen JR (2020) Intraregional trade shares for goods-producing industries: Rpc estimates using eu data. Pap Reg Sci 99(6):1583–1605

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leon-Ledesma M, Moro A (2020) The rise of services and balanced growth in theory and data. Am Econ J Macroecon 12(4):109–46

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • LeSage JP, Llano C (2016) A spatial interaction model with spatially structured origin and destination effects. Spatial econometric interaction modelling pp 171–197

  • LeSage JP, Pace RK (2008) Spatial econometric modeling of origin-destination flows*. J Reg Sci 48(5):941–967

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • LeSage JP, Pace RK (2008) Spatial econometric modeling of origin-destination flows. J Reg Sci 48(5):941–967

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • LeSage JP, Polasek W (2008) Incorporating transportation network structure in spatial econometric models of commodity flows. Spat Econ Anal 3(2):225–245

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • LeSage JP, Thomas-Agnan C (2015) Interpreting spatial econometric origin-destination flow models. J Reg Sci 55(2):188–208

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leung Y, Mei CL, Zhang WX (2000) Statistical tests for spatial nonstationarity based on the geographically weighted regression model. Environment and Planning A: Economy and Space 32(1):9–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu W, Li X, Liu H, Tang Z, Guan D (2015) Estimating inter-regional trade flows in china: A sector-specific statistical model. J Geogr Sci 25:1247–1263

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Metulini R, Patuelli R, Griffith DA (2018) A spatial-filtering zero-inflated approach to the estimation of the gravity model of trade. Econometrics 6(1):9

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nijkamp P, Ratajczak W (2021) Gravitational analysis in regional science and spatial economics: A vector gradient approach to trade. Int Reg Sci Rev 44(3–4):400–431

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2020) OECD Regions and Cities at a Glance 2020. https://www.oecd-ilibrary.org/content/publication/959d5ba0-en

  • Panicciá R, Rosignoli S (2018) A methodology for building multiregional supply and use tables for italy. Tech. rep, IRPET - STUDI E APPROFONDIMENTI

    Google Scholar 

  • Partridge MD, Rickman DS, Rose Olfert M, Tan Y (2017) International trade and local labor markets: Do foreign and domestic shocks affect regions differently? Journal of Economic Geography 17(2):375–409

    Google Scholar 

  • Persyn D, Díaz-Lanchas J, Barbero J (2020) Estimating road transport costs between and within european union regions. Transport Policy

  • Pfaffermayr M (2020) Constrained poisson pseudo maximum likelihood estimation of structural gravity models. International Economics 161:188–198

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Piras R (2020) Internal migration in italy: The role of migration networks. Italian Economic Journal 6(1):157–195

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ramondo N, Rodríguez-Clare A, Saborío-Rodríguez M (2016) Trade, domestic frictions, and scale effects. American Economic Review 106(10):3159–3184

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reissl S, Caiani A, Lamperti F, Guerini M, Vanni F, Fagiolo G, Ferraresi T, Ghezzi L, Napoletano M, Roventini A (2022) Assessing the economic impact of lockdowns in italy: A computational input-output approach. Ind Corp Chang 31(2):358–409

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik D (2013) Unconditional convergence in manufacturing. Q J Econ 128(1):165–204

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rungi A, Biancalani F (2019) Heterogeneous firms and the north-south divide in italy. Italian Economic Journal 5(3):325–347

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Santagata M (2022) Roads and intra-national trade: Evidence from italian regions. Papers in Regional Science

  • Santamaría M, Ventura J, Yeşilbayraktar U (2023) Exploring european regional trade. Journal of International Economics p 103747

  • Sellner R, Fischer MM, Koch M (2013) A spatial autoregressive poisson gravity model. Geogr Anal 45(2):180–201

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Silva JS, Tenreyro S (2006) The log of gravity. Rev Econ Stat 88(4):641–658

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sopranzetti S (2018) The italian districts in the global value chains. Italian Economic Journal 4(3):497–522

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taglioni D, Baldwin R (2014) Gravity chains: Estimating bilateral trade flows when parts and components trade is important. Journal of Banking and Financial Economics (2 (2)):61–82

  • Thissen M, Van Oort F, Diodato D, Ruijs A (2013) Regional competitiveness and smart specialization in Europe: Place-based development in international economic networks. Edward Elgar Publishing

  • Thissen M, Ivanova O, Mandras G, Husby T (2019) European NUTS 2 regions: construction of interregional trade-linked Supply and Use tables with consistent transport flows. JRC Working Papers on Territorial Modelling and Analysis 2019-01, Joint Research Centre (Seville site), https://ideas.repec.org/p/ipt/termod/201901.html

  • Thomas-Agnan C, LeSage JP (2021) Spatial econometric od-flow models. Handbook of regional science pp 2179–2199

  • Tranos E, Carrascal-Incera A, Willis G (2022) Using the web to predict regional trade flows: Data extraction, modeling, and validation. Annals of the American Association of Geographers pp 1–23

  • Vega SH, Elhorst JP (2016) A regional unemployment model simultaneously accounting for serial dynamics, spatial dependence and common factors. Reg Sci Urban Econ 60:85–95

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yotov YV (2022) On the role of domestic trade flows for estimating the gravity model of trade. Contemp Econ Policy 40(3):526–540

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yotov YV, Piermartini R, Larch M, et al. (2016) An Advanced Guide to Trade Policy Analysis: The Structural Gravity Model. WTO iLibrary

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Elisa Fusco.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

This paper has been developed at the Department of Finance-Italian Ministry of Economy and Finance under the project-Assistance for the assessment of environmental tax reforms’, funded by the European Commission-DG Reform, in collaboration with The World Bank. We are particularly grateful to the Editor and two anonymous reviewers for suggestions and comments. We also thank Stefano Curto, Marco Manzo, Maria Teresa Monteduro, Gavino Mura, Maria Alessandra Tullio, Hasan Dudu, Louise Wandhal-Jensen and Jan Ignacy Witajewski-Baltvilks, and the participants at different seminars and conferences. We wish to thank Sogei spa for the support. The views expressed in the paper do not reflect those of the institutions of affiliation. The usual disclaimer applies. Disclaimer: The findings, interpretations and conclusions expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the view of the European Commission, Italian Ministry of Economy and Finance, Sogei spa, World Bank Group, its Board of Directors or the governments they represent. The author, Pasquale Giacobbe, was working at Sogei SpA at the time of writing.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 A.1 Dataset description

See Tables 9, 10, 11

Table 9 Italian regions
Table 10 NACE rev.2 Level 1
Table 11 CPA 20 labels

1.2 A.2 Reconstruction of B2C Flows: Additional Information

We report below the different sub-steps used to reconstruct bilateral trade flows in final consumption from administrative VAT data.

Step 1: Transformation of VT data from fiscal domicile to plant location of seller

In the first step, a bridge matrix derived from IRAP (Regional tax on productive activities) databaseFootnote 20 is applied to VT data \(vt_{od,s}^{domicile}\) for the transformation from location by tax domicile to the location by the production plant. In detail, we use the information about the (net) value of production provided by fiscal domicile and plant location. This operation is conducted by calculating a re-proportioning coefficient \(\xi _{o,s}\) for each origin region o and sector s, which is the ratio between the value of net production per plant \(VNP_{o,s}^{plant}\) and the value of net production per domicile \(VNP_{o,s}^{domicile}\).

$$\begin{aligned} \xi _{o,s} = \frac{VNP_{o,s}^{plant}}{VNP_{o,s}^{domicile}} \end{aligned}$$
(11)

Then, this coefficient is multiplied by the taxable transactions \(vt_{od,s}^{domicile}\) obtaining a re-proportioned value of the total amount of taxable transactions \(\sum _d vt_{od,s}^{plant}\) in the region o and each sector s.

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _d vt_{od,s}^{plant} = \sum _d vt_{od,s}^{domicile} \xi _{o,s} \end{aligned}$$
(12)

Finally, these values are distributed for each pair of regions od according to the weight of the taxable operations in the initial data \(vt_{od,s}^{domicile}\).

$$\begin{aligned} VT_{od,s}^{plant} = \frac{vt_{od,s}^{domicile}}{\sum _d vt_{od,s}^{domicile}}\sum _d vt_{od,s}^{plant} \end{aligned}$$
(13)

Step 2: Converting VT Data From Activity Sector to Commodity

In a second step, an additional bridge matrix \(\Phi \), derived from national accounting data,Footnote 21 is applied to VT data by plant and sector \(VT_{od,s}^{plant}\) to distribute them by commodities i. \(\Phi \) is a bridge matrix with sectors s and commodities i as rows and columns, respectively. Each value \(\Phi _{is}\) of this matrix represents the national output of commodity i produced by sector s, i.e., \(Output_{nat,is}\) with respect to the total output of commodity i:

$$\begin{aligned} \Phi _{is} = \frac{Output_{nat,is}}{\sum _i Output_{nat,is}} \end{aligned}$$
(14)

Hence, we obtain the estimated output of commodities for each region.

$$\begin{aligned} VT_{od,i}^{plant} = \sum _{s} VT_{od,s}^{plant} \Phi _{is} \end{aligned}$$
(15)

Step 3: Cleaning VT Data From Margin Bias

In a third step, once the VT data framework by plant and commodity for each region are obtained, we need to correct for margins’ bias on electricity, trade, and transport. These three sectors represent a subset \(g \in I\), where I is the commodities’ set. The VT data, by construction, attribute to margins’ commodities g some taxable transactions which actually belong to other commodities \(i \ne g\), e.g., the agriculture commodity produced by region o and transported and sold to region d is attributed to the transport commodity instead of agriculture commodity.

To avoid this bias, we have to identify for each region o and commodity g, how much of the value of the taxable transactions (linked to g) should be attributed to margin and how much to the amount of produced goods and services. This operation is conducted by using data on national trade, transport marginsFootnote 22 and national output.Footnote 23 Then, we re-distribute the identified margin values to the commodities object of the effective trade flow.

The margins (labeled as Mar in the formulas) identification is obtained by applying shares \(\sigma _g\) to the VT data on plant and commodity. \(\sigma _g\) defines for each commodity g the amount of output to be considered as margin (e.g., 14%, 84%, and 15% of the electricity, trade, and transport commodities are margins and have to be allocated among all the other commodities as flows). These shares are calculated as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \sigma _g = \frac{Mar_{nat,ii}}{\sum _s Output_{nat,is}}, \forall i = g \end{aligned}$$
(16)

This step leads to the estimation of the margins \(M_ {od,g}\) for the three commodities g, which indicate the amount of sales of electricity, trade, and transport that has to be reallocated between all the other commodities.

$$\begin{aligned} M_{od,g} = VT_{od,i}^{plant} \sigma _g \end{aligned}$$
(17)

At this stage, we need to reallocate these quantities \(M_{od,g}\) across all the other commodities. Therefore, we define \(\eta _{ig}\) which represents the distribution of margin g among all the other commodities i. These values are calculated as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \eta _{ig} = - \frac{Mar_{nat,ig}}{\sum _i Mar_{nat,ig}} \end{aligned}$$
(18)

Now we apply these percentages to the margins \(M_{od,g}\), in order to reallocate the margins of commodity g to all the others as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta M_{od, ig} = \eta _{ig} M_{od,g} \end{aligned}$$
(19)

Hence, we correct the VT data by plant and commodities by reallocating the margins:

$$\begin{aligned} {\hat{VT}}_{od,i}^{plant} = VT_{od,i}^{plant} + \sum _g \Delta M_{od,ig}, \end{aligned}$$
(20)

where \({\hat{VT}}_{od,i}^{plant}\) represents the value of the trade flow of commodity i from region o (by plant) to region d (i.e., source-side).

Step 4: Reshaping the point of view from seller side to buyer side

At this stage, we need to change the point of view by switching from the source side to the destination side (i.e., \({\hat{VT}}_{od,i}^{plant} \rightarrow {\hat{VT}}_{do,i}^{plant}\)).

Finally, to make the estimation of administrative data coherent with the national accounting data, we transform \({\hat{VT}}_{do,i}^{plant}\) in shares \(\tau _{d,i}\). These shares are then applied to aggregated regionalized household expenditure by CPAFootnote 24 net to imports linked to households.Footnote 25

$$\begin{aligned} \tau _{d,i} = \frac{{\hat{VT}}_{do,i}^{plant}}{\sum _o {\hat{VT}}_{do,i}^{plant}} \end{aligned}$$
(21)
$$\begin{aligned} {\hat{VT}}_{do,i}^{plant} = (HH_{d,i} - Import_{d,i}^{HH}) \tau _{d,i}, \end{aligned}$$
(22)

where \(HH_{d,i}\) is the households’ consumption in the destination region d.Footnote 26 We obtain the flows of the household’s final consumption by destination region and commodity \({\hat{VT}}_{do,i}\) which represent the response variable for our analysis, namely, \(Y_{hh}\).

1.3 A.3 Estimation of B2B Flows: Additional Results

We report below additional information regarding the variables used to correct B2C trade flows in order to obtain B2B trade flows, as explained in the main text (Tables 12, 13).

Table 12 Origin–destination pairs inter-regions interaction
Table 13 Intra-commodities trade condition

1.4 A.4 Sensitivity Analysis

See Table 14.

Table 14 Lagrange multiplier test

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Baldassarre, A., Carullo, D., Di Caro, P. et al. A New Approach to Measure Italian Regional Trade Flows with Administrative Micro Firm-Level Data. Ital Econ J (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40797-023-00234-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40797-023-00234-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation