Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

You can’t always get what you want: why revolutionary outcomes so often diverge from revolutionary goals

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Revolutions rarely achieve their expressed goals, which often include greater economic prosperity, a more egalitarian distribution of rewards, ending corruption, and a less oppressive state. Yet there is no single reason for this, as revolutions of many types—violent and non-violent, radical and moderate—can produce similar outcomes. We explain this by treating revolutionary outcomes as the result of a decision tree process, in which outcomes are reached by a series of steps in which only the initial state of each step and the events at that junction determine the subsequent step. This simplification allows us to identify numerous pathways by which revolutions can unfold. However, relatively few such trajectories lead to stable constitutional regimes.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. This independence of prior conditions in determining the outcome at each step is known as the “Markov property,” and makes this model a Markov decision tree (Sheskin, 2016). In a Markov decision tree, actions or events acting on a system in state So produce a transition to one or more states S1, S2 … with probabilities p1, p 2 …. These probabilities may be fixed or stochastic. In the Markov decision tree, the probabilities for each outcome depend jointly on the condition at Sn and an event or action occurring at that point. Thus, the outcomes of the decision tree can be generated by the events (that occur with varying probabilities) and/or choices made by groups or individuals at each step. This model therefore allows for the interaction of actions (choices) and events at multiple points in the post-revolutionary process to shape outcomes in a sequence of steps that can diverge at the specified decision tree points. In the model developed here, the next outcome at each step is fully determined by the conditions and actions at that step, so the probabilities are deterministic at each step. Thus, at step 1, if radicals take power we assume the result is always a radical authoritarian regime. At step 4, we assume that if a moderate revolutionary regime faces major crises, but does not control a well-organized and loyal national army, it will always be replaced by a radical revolutionary regime. Of course, one could further refine the model by estimating probabilities or specifying a stochastic probability regime, but we leave that complication aside in this paper. Setting the probabilities at each step to 1 allows us to simply map out the range of possible trajectories that can be produced from the decision tree.

References

  • Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. (2019). The Narrow Corridor: States, Societies and the Fate of Liberty. Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baker, K., & Edelstein, D. (Eds.). (2015). Scripting revolution: A historical approach to the comparative study of revolutions. Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barany, Z. (2016). How armies respond to revolutions and why. Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Beck, C., Bukovansky, M., Chenoweth, E., Lawson, G., Nepstad, S. E., & Ritter, D. (2022). On revolutions: Unruly politics in the contemporary world. Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Beissinger, M. R. (2022). The revolutionary city: Urbanization and the global transformation of rebellion. Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bell, D. (2021). The atlantic revolutions. In D. Motadel (Ed.), Revolutionary world: Global upheaval in the modern age (pp. 38–65). Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Brinton, C. (1965). The anatomy of revolution (rev). Vintage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bueno De Mesquita, B., & Smith, A. (2009). Political survival and endogenous institutional change. Comparative Political Studies, 42, 167–197.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bueno de Mesquita, B., & Smith, A. (2010). Leader survival, revolutions, and the nature of government finance. American Journal of Political Science, 54, 936–950.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bueno de Mesquita, B., & Smith, A. (2011). The dictator’s handbook: Why bad behavior is almost always good politics. Public Affairs.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bueno De Mesquita, B., & Smith, A. (2017). Political succession: A model of coups, revolution, purges, and everyday politics. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 61, 707–743.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chenoweth, E., & Stephan, M. (2012). Why civil resistance works: The strategic logic of nonviolent conflict. Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chenoweth, E. (2020). The future of nonviolent resistance. Journal of Democracy, 31, 69–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chorley, K. (1973). Armies and the art of revolution. Beacon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clarke, K. (2023). The return of tyranny: How counterrevolutions emerge and succeed. In Paper Presented at the 27th World Congress of Political Science, Buenos Aires

  • Goldstone, J. A. (2009). Rethinking revolutions: Integrating origins, processes, and outcomes. Comparative Studies of South Asia, Africa, and the Middle East, 29, 8–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldstone, J. A. (2011). Cross-class coalitions in the making of the Arab revolts of 2011. Swiss Political Science Review, 17(4), 457–462.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldstone, J. A. (2016). Revolution and rebellion in the early modern world (2nd ed.). Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Goldstone, J. A. (2023). Revolutions: A very short introduction (2nd ed.). Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldstone, J.A., Grinin, L. & Korotayev, A. (2022). The phenomenon and theories of revolution. In J. A. Goldstone, L. Grinin & A. Korotayev (Eds.), Handbook of Revolutions in the 21st Century: New Waves of Revolution and the Causes and Effects of Disruptive Political Change (pp. 37–68) Springer Nature, .

  • Gorodnichenko, Y., & Roland, G. (2021). Culture, institutions and democratization. Public Choice, 187, 165–195.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grijalva, D. F. (2023). Revolutions of the mind, (threats of) actual revolutions, and institutional change. Public Choice. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-023-01069-6

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haggard, S., & Kaufman, R. R. (2016). Dictators and democrats: Masses, elites and regime change. Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hirst, C. (2022). Revolution, International Counterrevolution and World Order, PhD Dissertation London School of Economics.

  • Kuran, T. (1989). Sparks and prairie fires: A theory of unanticipated political revolution. Public Choice, 61, 41–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuran, T., & Romero, D. (2019). The logic of revolutions: Rational choice perspectives. In R. D. Congleton, B. Grofman, & S. Voigt (Eds.), The Oxford Handbook of Public Choice (Vol. 2, pp. 345–360). Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lawson, G. (2019). Anatomies of revolution. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Levitsky, S., & Way, L. (2022). Revolution and dictatorship: The violent origins of durable authoritarianism. Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Luo, Z., & Przeworski, A. (2023). Democracy and its vulnerabilities: Dynamics of democratic backsliding. Quarterly Journal of Political Science, 18, 105–130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markoff, J. (1996). The abolition of feudalism: Peasants, lords and legislators in the French revolution. Pennsylvania State University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, C. (2022). Revolutionary contagion and international politics. Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ober, J. (1998). The Athenian revolution. Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olsson-Yaouzis, N. (2012). An evolutionary dynamic of revolutions. Public Choice, 151, 497–515.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ritter, D. (2014). The iron cage of liberalism. Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Sheshkin, T. (2016). Markov chains and decision processes for engineers and managers. CRC Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Skocpol, T. (1979). States and social revolutions: A comparative analysis of France, Russia, and China. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, S. A. (2002). The Russian revolution: A very short introduction. Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1971). The paradox of revolution. Public Choice, 11, 89–99.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Walt, S. (1996). Revolution and war. Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jack A. Goldstone.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Goldstone, J.A. You can’t always get what you want: why revolutionary outcomes so often diverge from revolutionary goals. Public Choice (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-023-01092-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-023-01092-7

Keywords

Navigation