Skip to main content
Log in

A Simple City Equilibrium Model with an Application to Teleworking

  • Published:
Applied Mathematics & Optimization Submit manuscript

Abstract

We propose a simple semi-discrete spatial model where rents, wages and the density of population in a city can be deduced from free-mobility and equilibrium conditions on the labour and residential housing markets. We prove existence and (under stronger assumptions) uniqueness of the equilibrium. We extend our model to the case where teleworking is introduced. We present numerical simulations which shed light on the effect of teleworking on the structure of the city at equilibrium.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See in particular Fujita and Ogawa [8] for evidence of multiple equilibria. On the contrary, by variational and suitable convexity arguments, uniqueness results were derived by Blanchet, Mossay and Santambrogio [2] in a potential game setting which takes into account the housing market by congestion effects but not the labour market.

  2. Except under additional assumptions, such as radial symmetry as in Lucas and Rossi-Hansberg [11].

  3. Note that we are not assuming that the goods produced by firms and this consumption good are the same, and we are not looking for equilibrium in the markets for these goods (which can be exported or imported from outside the city) that is why we can normalize these prices to 1.

  4. Of course, it is also possible to have a location dependent supply for land and to replace (2.10) by \(\mu (x) S(x)= \alpha (x)\) for a given nonnegative function \(\alpha \).

  5. Note that the function \(R_\sigma (x, \cdot )\) defined in (2.13) is not strictly convex, seen as a function of all wages \((w_0, w_1, \ldots , w_N)\) (because it behaves in a linear way when adding a common constant to all wages including \(w_0\)), but it is strictly convex with respect to \(w=(w_1, \ldots , w_N)\) for fixed \(w_0\), which is the situation we consider here.

  6. An easy way to rule out ties is the following. Since \(\mu _w\) is absolutely continuous, one way to ensure that \(V_i(w)\setminus V_i^s(w)\) is negligible is to assume that for every ij with \(i\ne j\) and any \(\lambda \in \mathbb {R}\), the level set \(\{x\in X \;: \; c_i(x)-c_j(x)=\lambda \}\) is Lebesgue-negligible.

References

  1. Behrens, K., Kichko, S., Thisse, J.-F.: Working from Home: Too Much of a Good Thing? CESifo Working Paper Series 8831, CESifo, vol. 2 (2021)

  2. Blanchet, A., Mossay, P., Santambrogio, F.: Existence and uniqueness of equilibrium for a spatial model of social interactions. Int. Econom. Rev. 57(1), 31–59 (2016)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  3. Carlier, G., Ekeland, I.: Equilibrium structure of a bidimensional asymmetric city. Nonlinear Anal. Real World Appl. 8(3), 725–748 (2007)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  4. Carlier, G., Mallozzi, L.: Optimal monopoly pricing with congestion and random utility via partial mass transport. J. Math. Anal. Appl. 457(2), 1218–1231 (2018)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  5. Crippa, G., Jimenez, C., Pratelli, A.: Optimum and equilibrium in a transport problem with queue penalization effect. Adv. Calc. Var. 2(3), 207–246 (2009)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  6. Delventhal, M.J., Parkhomenko, A.: Spatial implications of telecommuting. (2022)

  7. Delventhal, M.J., Kwon, E., Parkhomenko, A.: Jue insight: how do cities change when we work from home? JUE insights: COVID-19 and cities. J. Urban Econom. 127, 103331 (2022)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Fujita, M., Ogawa, H.: Multiple equilibria and structural transition of non-monocentric urban configurations. Reg. Sci. Urban Econ. 12(2), 161–196 (1982)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Galichon, A.: Optimal Transport Methods in Economics. Princeton University Press, Princeton (2016)

    Book  Google Scholar 

  10. Gaspar, J., Glaeser, E.L.: Information technology and the future of cities. J. Urban Econ. 43(1), 136–156 (1998)

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  11. Lucas, R.E., Jr., Rossi-Hansberg, E.: On the internal structure of cities. Econometrica 70(4), 1445–1476 (2002)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  12. More, J.J., Garbow, B.S., Hillstrom, K.E.: User Guide for Minpack-1 [in Fortran], vol. 8. Technical Report, Argonne National Lab, Lemont (1980)

  13. Nocedal, J., Wright, S.: Numerical Optimization. Springer Series in Operations Research and Financial Engineering, Springer, New York (2006)

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  14. Powell, M.J.D.: A hybrid method for nonlinear equations. In: Numerical Methods for Nonlinear Algebraic Equations (Proc. Conf., Univ. Essex, Colchester, 1969), pp. 87–114 (1970)

Download references

Acknowledgements

All the authors were partially supported by the ANR (Agence Nationale de la Recherche) through MFG Project ANR-16-CE40-0015-01. Y.A. and Q.P. acknowledge partial support from the Chair Finance and Sustainable Development and the FiME Lab (Institut Europlace de Finance). The paper was completed when Y.A spent a semester at INRIA matherials. G.C. acknowledges the support of the Lagrange Mathematics and Computing Research Center.

Funding

The authors have not disclosed any funding.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Quentin Petit.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

We disclose any interest directly or indirectly related to the work submitted for publication.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 A. Softmax as the Expectation of a Max

Let us first recall that a random variable \(\varepsilon \) has a centered standard Gumbel distribution if its cdf has the following double exponential form:

$$\begin{aligned}\mathbb {P}(\varepsilon \le t)=\exp (-\exp (-t-\gamma )), \; \forall t\in \mathbb {R}, \text{ with } \gamma :=-\int _0^{+\infty } \log (s) \exp (-s) \text{ d }s.\end{aligned}$$

Consider now \(\varepsilon _0, \cdots , \varepsilon _N\), \(N+1\) i.i.d. distributed with a centered standard Gumbel and for \(\beta =\beta _0, \ldots , \beta _N \in \mathbb {R}^{N+1}\) set

$$\begin{aligned}V(\beta ):=\mathbb {E}(\max _{i=0, \ldots , N} (\beta _i + \varepsilon _i))\end{aligned}$$

since

$$\begin{aligned}\mathbb {P}( (\max _{i=0, \ldots , N} (\beta _i + \varepsilon _i) \le t)=\exp \Big (-\Lambda (\beta ) \exp (-t-\gamma )\Big ), \text{ with } \Lambda (\beta )=\sum _{i=0}^N e^{\beta _i}\end{aligned}$$

we have

$$\begin{aligned}\begin{aligned} V(\beta )&=\int _{\mathbb {R}} t \exp \Big (- \exp (-t +\log \Lambda (\beta )-\gamma )\Big ) \exp (-t +\log \Lambda (\beta )-\gamma ) \text{ d }t \\&= \int _{\mathbb {R}} (s+ \log (\Lambda (\beta )) \exp \Big (- \exp (-s -\gamma )\Big ) \exp (-s -\gamma ) \text{ d }s \\&= \mathbb {E}( \varepsilon + \log (\Lambda (\beta )))= \log (\Lambda (\beta ))=\log \Big (\sum _{i=0}^N e^{\beta _i} \Big ). \end{aligned}\end{aligned}$$

Recalling the expression (2.13) for \(R_\sigma \), we thus have

$$\begin{aligned}\mathbb {E}(\max _{i=0, \ldots , N} (w_i-c_i(x)+\sigma \varepsilon _i))= \sigma \log \Big (\sum _{i=0}^N e^{\frac{w_i-c_i(x)}{\sigma }} \Big ) = R_\sigma (x,w)\end{aligned}$$

which shows (2.15). Moreover, it follows from Lebesgue’s dominated convergence theorem that V is differentiable with

$$\begin{aligned}\frac{\partial V}{\partial \beta _i} (\beta )= \mathbb {P}( \beta _i+\varepsilon _i \ge \beta _j +\varepsilon _j, \; \forall j=0, \ldots , N)=\frac{e^{\beta _i}}{\sum _{j=0}^N e^{\beta _j}}\end{aligned}$$

which shows formula (2.16).

1.2 B. Existence and Uniqueness of Equilibria in the Teleworking Model

1.2.1 Existence

Under the assumptions of Sect. 4, we claim that there exists equilibrium wages i.e. a vector \(\widetilde{w}\in \mathbb {R}_+^{2N}\) solving the fixed-point equation (4.14). To see this, we first argue as in Lemma 3.1 and find that for every \(\mu \in {{\mathscr {P}}}(X)\), the functional \(\widetilde{J}_\mu \) defined in (4.13) admits a unique minimizer \(\widetilde{w}=(w_i^k)_{i=1, \ldots ,N, k=1,2}\) which satisfies

$$\begin{aligned}\max _{i,k} w_i^k + \sum _{i=1}^N \widetilde{\pi }_i(w_i^1, w_i^2) \le \overline{w}:= 2M + \sum _{i=1}^N \widetilde{\pi }_i(w_0, w_0) +\sigma \log (2N+1)+ w_0\end{aligned}$$

where \(M:=\max _i \Vert c_i\Vert _{\infty }\). Thanks to the nonnegativity of \(\widetilde{\pi }_i\) and (4.5), we find that the minimizer of \(\widetilde{J}_\mu \) belongs to \([\underline{w}, \overline{w}]^{2N}\) where \(0<\underline{w}\le \overline{w}\) are bounds that do not depend on \(\mu \). The conclusion of Lemma 3.1 still holds for \(\widetilde{J}_\mu \) so that the existence of an equilibrium follows from Brouwer’s theorem exactly as in the proof of theorem 3.2.

1.2.2 Uniqueness

Let us now further assume that the production functions \(\widetilde{f}_i\) are of class \(C^2\) on \((0,+\infty )^2\) and that (4.15) holds. Since \(-\nabla \widetilde{f}_i\) is the inverse of \(\nabla \widetilde{\pi }_i\), this implies that for every \((w^1, w^2)\in [\underline{w}, \overline{w}]^2\), the \(2\times 2\) matrix \(D^2 \widetilde{\pi }_i(w^1, w^2)\) is positive definite so that its smallest eigenvalue \(\lambda _{\min }(D^2 \widetilde{\pi }_i(w^1, w^2))\) is positive (and depends on \((w^1, w^2)\in [\underline{w}, \overline{w}]^2\) in a continuous way). Setting \(\alpha :=\frac{\theta }{1-\theta }\), and

$$\begin{aligned}\widetilde{\mu }(x, \widetilde{w}, \alpha ):=\frac{ \widetilde{R}_\sigma (x, \widetilde{w})^{\alpha }}{\int _X \widetilde{R}_\sigma (y, \widetilde{w})^{\alpha } \text{ d } y }, \; \forall (x, \widetilde{w}, \alpha ) \in X\times \mathbb {R}_+^{2N} \times \mathbb {R}_+\end{aligned}$$

we write the system of equilibrium conditions as the system of 2N equations in the 2N unknown \(\widetilde{w}:=(w_1^1, w_1^2, \ldots w_N^1, w_N^2)\)

$$\begin{aligned}\widetilde{G}(\widetilde{w}, \alpha )=0, \text{ where } \widetilde{G}_i^k(\widetilde{w}, \alpha )=\frac{\partial \widetilde{\pi }_i}{\partial w_i^k}(w_i^1, w_i^2) + \int _X \frac{\partial \widetilde{R}_{\sigma }}{\partial w_i^k} \widetilde{\mu }(x, \widetilde{w}, \alpha ) \text{ d }x \end{aligned}$$

so that the Jacobian matrix (with respect to \(\widetilde{w}\)) \(\widetilde{A}\) of \(\widetilde{G}\) reads

$$\begin{aligned}\begin{aligned} \widetilde{A}=&\left( \begin{array}{ccccc} D^2 \widetilde{\pi }_1(w_1^1, w_1^2) &{} O &{} O &{} \cdots &{} O \\ O &{} D^2 \widetilde{\pi }_2(w_2^1, w_2^2) &{} O &{} \cdots &{} O\\ \cdot &{} \cdot &{} \cdot &{} \cdots &{} \cdot \\ \cdot &{} \cdot &{} \cdot &{} \cdots &{} \cdot \\ O &{} O &{} O &{} \cdots &{} D^2 \widetilde{\pi }_N(w_N^1, w_N^2) \\ \end{array}\right) \\&+ \int _X D^2_{\widetilde{w}\widetilde{w}} \widetilde{R}_{\sigma } \widetilde{\mu }\\&+ \int _X \nabla _{\widetilde{w}} \widetilde{R}_\sigma \nabla _{\widetilde{w}} \widetilde{\mu }^{\top } \end{aligned}\end{aligned}$$

where the matrix in the first line is written in \(2\times 2\) block-diagonal form (and O denotes the zero \(2\times 2\) matrix) and the matrix on the second line is positive definite. Since all wages \(w_i^k\) belong to \([\underline{w}, \overline{w}] \subset (0,+\infty )\), setting

$$\begin{aligned}\nu :=\min _{i=1, \ldots , N} \min _{(w^1, w^2) \in [\underline{w}, \overline{w}]^2} \lambda _{\min }(D^2 \widetilde{\pi }_i(w^1, w^2)) >0,\end{aligned}$$

we have, for every \(\widetilde{\xi }\in \mathbb {R}^{2N}\setminus \{0\}\)

$$\begin{aligned}\widetilde{A}\widetilde{\xi }\cdot \widetilde{\xi }> \Big ( \nu - \int _X \vert \nabla _{\widetilde{w}} \widetilde{R}_\sigma \vert \; \vert \nabla _{\widetilde{w}} \widetilde{\mu }\vert \Big ) \vert \widetilde{\xi }\vert ^2. \end{aligned}$$

Obviously \(\vert \nabla _{\widetilde{w}} \widetilde{R}_\sigma \vert \le \sqrt{2N}\) and assuming that \(\alpha \le 1\), arguing as in the proof of theorem 3.3, we get

$$\begin{aligned} \int _X \vert \nabla _{\widetilde{w}} \widetilde{\mu }\vert \le \frac{ \alpha }{w_0} \sqrt{2N}\end{aligned}$$

hence, we deduce that \(\widetilde{A}\) is invertible as soon as

$$\begin{aligned} \alpha \le \frac{ w_0 \nu }{ 2N} \end{aligned}$$

For such a choice of \(\alpha \), uniqueness of the equilibrium can be shown exactly as in the proof of theorem 3.3.

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Achdou, Y., Carlier, G., Petit, Q. et al. A Simple City Equilibrium Model with an Application to Teleworking. Appl Math Optim 88, 60 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00245-023-10035-z

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00245-023-10035-z

Keywords

Mathematics Subject Classification

Navigation