Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Pollution control, worker productivity, and wage inequality

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
The Annals of Regional Science Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Poor environmental quality can reduce worker productivity, but how this effect is associated with skilled-unskilled wage inequality is still unclear. This paper studies how stricter pollution control impacts wage inequality in the presence of such a worker productivity effect by establishing general equilibrium models with two urban sectors and by conducting empirical analysis with country-level panel data. The models show that when the non-polluting sector is under perfect competition, wage inequality is closely related to the worker productivity effect, while when it is under monopolistic competition, productivity gains of skilled workers from stricter pollution control exhibit complete pass-through. Empirical analysis suggests that the worker productivity effect of pollution control is unskill-biased, which helps mitigate inequality.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The evidence comes from both the nationwide manufacturing (Fu et al. 2021) and many specific jobs, which include agricultural workers (Graff Zivin and Neidell 2012; Chang et al. 2016), call center workers (Chang et al. 2019), and assembly workers (He et al. 2019; Adhvaryu et al. 2022).

  2. Fullerton and Heutel (2007) summarize the two channels as the uses side and the sources side of income when they investigate the incidence of environmental taxes.

  3. Introducing a rural sector into the models does not change the main results of this paper, but significantly complicates the analytical solutions. We do not limit the model background to developed or developing countries for three reasons. First, the evidence for the effect of pollution on worker productivity comes from both developed and developing countries. Second, skilled-unskilled wage inequality is a very important phenomenon in both developed and developing countries. Third, when a developing country reaches the Lewis turning point, rural labor may not be abundant any more.

  4. If we use \(u_S\) and \(u_U\), then the two equations can be written as \({\theta _{SX}}{{\hat{w}}_S} + {\theta _{KX}}{\hat{r}} ={\theta _{SX}}\hat{u}_S\) and \({\theta _{UY}}{{\hat{w}}_U} + {\theta _{KY}}{\hat{r}} + {\theta _{EY}}{\hat{\rho }} = {\theta _{UY}}\hat{u}_U\), which link the wage rates to worker productivity directly, rather than via pollution.

  5. It is equivalent to treat the shadow price of pollution \(\rho\) as the exogenous environmental tax, and let pollution permits E be determined endogenously.

  6. When pollution is a by-product of the unskilled sector, we can still obtain an effect similar to the complementary effect. In this case, stricter pollution control reduces unskilled output, and thus, the demand for unskilled workers will fall.

  7. Appendix B provides a discussion on the constant returns to scale production function as in Sect. 2, and it shows that the main results in Sect. 3 may still hold.

  8. Anwar (2010) introduces monopolistic competition into the service sector, and output of the service sector is treated as intermediate goods for the industrial sector. In this paper, we introduce monopolistic competition into the skilled sector, and output of the skilled sector is treated as final goods. We depart from Anwar (2010) by interpreting u as skilled worker productivity associated with pollution. The cost function may adopt other forms (e.g., Anwar 2009; Zhang 2012, 2013).

  9. It is equivalent to adopt a cost function \(C = fr + x{w_S}/u\) and a corresponding production function \(x=ul\) with \(k \ge f\). With this setting, we can assume \(u'\left( E \right) < 0\).

  10. In general, wage inequality is closely related to income inequality. Similar to Ee et al. (2018), we use the Gini index as a proxy of wage inequality.

  11. We control the growth rate of GDP in Eq. (30) rather than GDP per capita (2017 PPP), because real GDP is used to estimate worker productivity. The regression results are similar when we use real GDP as a control.

  12. There could also be the possibility that inequality can impact the strength of pollution control. To try to address the issue of simultaneity, we replace pollution control and worker productivity in the empirical model (30) with their one-year lags, and find that the empirical results in subsection 4.3 are still robust.

References

  • Adhvaryu A, Kala N, Nyshadham A (2022) Management and shocks to worker productivity. J Polit Econ 130(1):1–47

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anwar S (2008) Labor inflow induced wage inequality and public infrastructure. Rev Dev Econ 12(4):792–802

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anwar S (2009) Sector specific foreign investment, labour inflow, economies of scale and welfare. Econ Model 26(3):626–630

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anwar S (2010) Wage inequality, increased competition, and trade liberalization: Short run vs long run. Rev Int Econ 18(3):574–581

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beladi H, Frasca R (1999) Pollution control under an urban binding minimum wage. Ann Reg Sci 33(4):523–533

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beladi H, Liu L, Oladi R (2013) On pollution permits and abatement. Econ Lett 119(3):302–305

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bharadwaj P, Gibson M, Graff Zivin J, Neilson C (2017) Gray matters: Fetal pollution exposure and human capital formation. J Assoc Environ Resour Econ 4(2):505–542

    Google Scholar 

  • Botta E, Koźluk T (2014) Measuring environmental policy stringency in OECD countries: A composite index approach. OECD Economics Department Working Papers No. 1177

  • Chang T, Graff Zivin J, Gross T, Neidell M (2016) Particulate pollution and the productivity of pear packers. Am Econ J Econ Pol 8(3):141–69

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang TY, Graff Zivin J, Gross T, Neidell M (2019) The effect of pollution on worker productivity: Evidence from call center workers in China. Am Econ J Appl Econ 11(1):151–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chao C-C, Laffargue J-P, Sgro PM (2012) Environmental control, wage inequality and national welfare in a tourism economy. Int Rev Econ Finance 22(1):201–207

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chaudhuri S (2005) Labour market distortion, technology transfer and gainful effects of foreign capital. Manch Sch 73(2):214–227

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chaudhuri S, Kumar Dwibedi J, Biswas A (2017) Subsidizing healthcare in the presence of market distortions. Econ Model 64:539–552

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Copeland BR, Taylor MS (1999) Trade, spatial separation, and the environment. J Int Econ 47(1):137–168

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit AK, Stiglitz JE (1977) Monopolistic competition and optimum product diversity. Am Econ Rev 67(3):297–308

    Google Scholar 

  • Ee MS, Chao C-C, Liu X, Yu ESH (2018) Environmental policy, firm dynamics and wage inequality in developing countries. Int Rev Econ Finance 57:70–85

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feenstra RC, Inklaar R, Timmer MP (2015) The next generation of the Penn World Table. Am Econ Rev 105(10):3150–82

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fu S, Viard VB, Zhang P (2021) Air pollution and manufacturing firm productivity: Nationwide estimates for China. Econ J 131(640):3241–3273

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fujita M, Krugman PR, Venables A (1999) The spatial economy: Cities, regions, and international trade. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Fullerton D, Heutel G (2007) The general equilibrium incidence of environmental taxes. J Public Econ 91(3):571–591

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fullerton D, Monti H (2013) Can pollution tax rebates protect low-wage earners? J Environ Econ Manag 66(3):539–553

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gassebner M, Gaston N, Lamla MJ (2008) Relief for the environment? The importance of an increasingly unimportant industrial sector. Econ Inq 46(2):160–178

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Graff Zivin J, Neidell M (2012) The impact of pollution on worker productivity. Am Econ Rev 102(7):3652–73

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • He J, Liu H, Salvo A (2019) Severe air pollution and labor productivity: evidence from industrial towns in China. Am Econ J Appl Econ 11(1):173–201

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kondoh K, Yabuuchi S (2012) Unemployment, environmental policy, and international migration. J Int Trade Econ Dev 21(5):677–690

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li X, Fu H, Wu Y (2020) Pollution mitigation, unemployment rate and wage inequality in the presence of agricultural pollution. China Econ Rev 61:101425

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li X, Xu Y, Wang D (2014) Environment and labor movement of skilled labor and unskilled labor between sectors. Econ Model 38:367–371

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oladi R, Beladi H (2015) On foreign aid, pollution and abatement. Environ Dev Econ 20(6):797–812

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pan L, Zhou Y (2013) International factor mobility, environmental pollution and skilled-unskilled wage inequality in developing countries. Econ Model 33:826–831

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pi J, Shi S (2019) Public pollution abatement and wage inequality. J Int Trade Econ Dev 28(2):257–275

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pi J, Zhang P (2016) Hukou system reforms and skilled-unskilled wage inequality in China. China Econ Rev 41:90–103

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pi J, Zhang P (2017) Foreign capital, pollution control, and wage inequality in developing countries. Int Rev Econ Finance 48:280–288

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pi J, Zhang P (2018) Skill-biased technological change and wage inequality in developing countries. Int Rev Econ Finance 56:347–362

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rapanos VT (2007) Environmental taxation in a dualistic economy. Environ Dev Econ 12(1):73–89

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rivera-Batiz FL, Rivera-Batiz LA (1990) The effects of direct foreign investment in the presence of increasing returns due to specialization. J Dev Econ 34(1):287–307

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robinson HD (1985) Who pays for industrial pollution abatement? Rev Econ Stat 67(4):702–706

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solt F (2020) Measuring income inequality across countries and over time: The Standardized World income inequality database. Social Science Quarterly. SWIID Version 9.3, 2022

  • Tawada M, Nakamura A (2009) Environment and the Harris and Todaro paradoxes. In: Kamihigashi T, Zhao L (eds) International Trade & Economic Development. Springer, Berlin Heidelberg, Berlin, Heidelberg, pp 87–99

    Google Scholar 

  • Tawada M, Sun S (2010) Urban pollution, unemployment and national welfare in a dualistic economy. Rev Dev Econ 14(2):311–322

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang LFS (1990) Unemployment and the backward incidence of pollution control. J Environ Econ Manag 18(3):292–298

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wu Y, Li X (2021) International factor mobility and environment in a dual agricultural economy. Annals Reg Sci 66(1):75–89

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yohe GW (1979) The backward incidence of pollution control - some comparative statics in general equilibrium. J Environ Econ Manag 6(3):187–198

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang J (2012) Inflow of labour, producer services and wage inequality. Econ Lett 117(3):600–603

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang J (2013) Factor mobility and skilled-unskilled wage inequality in the presence of internationally traded product varieties. Econ Model 30:579–585

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang P (2019) Skill formation, environmental pollution, and wage inequality. Ann Reg Sci 62(2):405–424

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

This research is supported by Guangdong Planning Office of Philosophy and Social Science (GD22YLJ01) and Guangdong University of Foreign Studies (2022RC076). I thank two anonymous referees for helpful comments. All errors are my own.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Pengqing Zhang.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors have no competing interests to declare that are relevant to the content of this article.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix A: Proofs

Proof of Proposition 1

Writing Eqs. (7), (8), (13), and (14) in the matrix form, we have:

$$\begin{aligned} \left( {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {{\theta _{SX}}}&{}0&{}{{\theta _{KX}}}&{}0\\ 0&{}{{\theta _{UY}}}&{}{{\theta _{KY}}}&{}{{\theta _{EY}}}\\ {{\lambda _{KX}}{\sigma _{SKX}}}&{}{{\lambda _{KY}}{\sigma _{UKY}}}&{}{ - {A_1}}&{}0\\ 0&{}{{\sigma _{UEY}}}&{}0&{}{ - {\sigma _{UEY}}} \end{array}} \right) \left( {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {{{{\hat{w}}}_S}}\\ {{{{\hat{w}}}_U}}\\ {{\hat{r}}}\\ {{\hat{\rho }} } \end{array}} \right) = - \left( {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {{\varepsilon _S}{\theta _{SX}}}\\ {{\varepsilon _U}{\theta _{UY}}}\\ 0\\ { - 1} \end{array}} \right) {\hat{E}}, \end{aligned}$$

where \({A_1} = {\lambda _{KX}}{\sigma _{SKX}} + {\lambda _{KY}}{\sigma _{UKY}}\).

By solving the above equation, we can obtain:

$$\begin{aligned}{} & {} \frac{{{{{\hat{w}}}_S}}}{{{\hat{E}}}} = \frac{{{\theta _{SX}}{\sigma _{UEY}}\left[ {\left( {{\theta _{EY}} + {\theta _{UY}}} \right) {\lambda _{KX}}{\sigma _{SKX}} + {\lambda _{KY}}{\sigma _{UKY}}} \right] }}{{{\Delta _1}}}\left[ {{f_1}\left( {{\varepsilon _U}} \right) - {\varepsilon _S}} \right] , \\{} & {} \frac{{{{{\hat{w}}}_U}}}{{{\hat{E}}}} = \frac{{{\theta _{KY}}{\theta _{SX}}{\lambda _{KX}}{\sigma _{SKX}}{\sigma _{UEY}}}}{{{\Delta _1}}}\left[ {{\varepsilon _S} - {f_2}\left( {{\varepsilon _U}} \right) } \right] , \end{aligned}$$

where \(\Delta _1 = \sigma _{UEY}[ {\left( {{\theta _{EY}} + {\theta _{UY}}} \right) {\lambda _{KX}}{\sigma _{SKX}} + {\theta _{SX}}{\lambda _{KY}}{\sigma _{UKY}}} ]\), \(f_1( {{\varepsilon _U}} ) = {B_1}( {\varepsilon _U}{\theta _{UY}}{\sigma _{UEY}} - {\theta _{EY}} )\), \(f_2( \varepsilon _U ) = B_2 ( \varepsilon _U\theta _{UY}\sigma _{UEY} - \theta _{EY} )\), \({B_1} = \frac{{{\theta _{KX}}{\lambda _{KY}}{\sigma _{UKY}}}}{{{\theta _{SX}}{\sigma _{UEY}}\left[ {\left( {{\theta _{EY}} + {\theta _{UY}}} \right) {\lambda _{KX}}{\sigma _{SKX}} + {\lambda _{KY}}{\sigma _{UKY}}} \right] }}\), and \({B_2} = \frac{{{\lambda _{KX}}{\sigma _{SKX}} + {\theta _{SX}}{\lambda _{KY}}{\sigma _{UKY}}}}{{{\theta _{KY}}{\theta _{SX}}{\lambda _{KX}}{\sigma _{SKX}}{\sigma _{UEY}}}}\).

Wage inequality can be expressed by:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{{{{\hat{w}}}_S} - {{{\hat{w}}}_U}}}{{{\hat{E}}}} = \frac{{A_1 {\theta _{SX}}{\sigma _{UEY}}}}{{{\Delta _1}}}\left[ {{f_3}\left( {{\varepsilon _U}} \right) - {\varepsilon _S}} \right] , \end{aligned}$$

where \({f_3}\left( {{\varepsilon _U}} \right) = {B_3}\left( {{\varepsilon _U}{\theta _{UY}}{\sigma _{UEY}} - {\theta _{EY}}} \right)\), and \({B_3} = \frac{1}{{{\theta _{SX}}{\sigma _{UEY}}}}\). We can find that \({B_1}< {B_3} < {B_2}\).

The implications of stricter pollution control on the skilled wage rate, the unskilled wage rate, and wage inequality are summarized as follows:

  1. 1.

    When \({\varepsilon _U} < \frac{{{\theta _{EY}}}}{{{\theta _{UY}}{\sigma _{UEY}}}}\), we have \(\frac{{{{{\hat{w}}}_S}}}{{{\hat{E}}}} < 0\), \(\frac{{{{{\hat{w}}}_U}}}{{{\hat{E}}}} > 0\), and \(\frac{{{{{\hat{w}}}_S} - {{{\hat{w}}}_U}}}{{{\hat{E}}}} < 0\).

  2. 2.

    When \({\varepsilon _U} > \frac{{{\theta _{EY}}}}{{{\theta _{UY}}{\sigma _{UEY}}}}\), we have:

    1. (a)

      If \({\varepsilon _S} < {f_1}\left( {{\varepsilon _U}} \right)\), then \(\frac{{{{{\hat{w}}}_S}}}{{{\hat{E}}}} > 0\), \(\frac{{{{{\hat{w}}}_U}}}{{{\hat{E}}}} < 0\), and \(\frac{{{{{\hat{w}}}_S} - {{{\hat{w}}}_U}}}{{{\hat{E}}}} > 0\).

    2. (b)

      If \({f_1}\left( {{\varepsilon _U}} \right)< {\varepsilon _S} < {f_3}\left( {{\varepsilon _U}} \right)\), then \(\frac{{{{{\hat{w}}}_S}}}{{{\hat{E}}}} < 0\), \(\frac{{{{{\hat{w}}}_U}}}{{{\hat{E}}}} < 0\), and \(\frac{{{{{\hat{w}}}_S} - {{{\hat{w}}}_U}}}{{{\hat{E}}}} > 0\).

    3. (c)

      If \({f_3}\left( {{\varepsilon _U}} \right)< {\varepsilon _S} < {f_2}\left( {{\varepsilon _U}} \right)\), then \(\frac{{{{{\hat{w}}}_S}}}{{{\hat{E}}}} < 0\), \(\frac{{{{{\hat{w}}}_U}}}{{{\hat{E}}}} < 0\), and \(\frac{{{{{\hat{w}}}_S} - {{{\hat{w}}}_U}}}{{{\hat{E}}}} < 0\).

    4. (d)

      If \({\varepsilon _S} > {f_2}\left( {{\varepsilon _U}} \right)\), then \(\frac{{{{{\hat{w}}}_S}}}{{{\hat{E}}}} < 0\), \(\frac{{{{{\hat{w}}}_U}}}{{{\hat{E}}}} > 0\), and \(\frac{{{{{\hat{w}}}_S} - {{{\hat{w}}}_U}}}{{{\hat{E}}}} < 0\).

\(\square\)

Proof of Proposition 2

Stricter pollution control reduces the production cost of the skilled sector, which is simply because \(u'\left( E \right) > 0\). \({\varepsilon _S}\) measures the productivity effect of pollution control on skilled workers. It does not enter Eqs. (26) and (28), and it also does not enter the other equations in the economic system (i.e., Eqs. (4), (10), (12), and (22)).

Since Eqs. (4), (10), (12), (22), (26), and (28) pin down \({w_S}\), \({w_U}\), r, \(\rho\), n, and Y, these variables will not be affected by \({\varepsilon _S}\). When \({w_S}\), \({w_U}\), r, \(\rho\), n, and Y are solved from these equations, we can solve p from Eq. (23), which shows that p will be negatively affected by \({\varepsilon _S}\) originating from stricter pollution control (i.e., a reduction in E). From Eqs. (23) and (24), we have \({\hat{x}} = {\hat{r}} - {{\hat{w}}_S} - {\varepsilon _S}{\hat{E}}\). Hence, x will be positively affected by \({\varepsilon _S}\). Since new firms will enter the skilled sector, the results show that the productivity effect on skilled workers will decrease the relative price but increase output of the non-polluting good. \(\square\)

Proof of Proposition 3

Writing Eqs. (8), (14), (28), and (29) in the matrix form, we have:

$$\begin{aligned} \left( {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {{A_2}}&{}{ - {\alpha _U}}&{}{ - {\alpha _K}}&{}{ - {\alpha _E}}\\ 0&{}{{\theta _{UY}}}&{}{{\theta _{KY}}}&{}{{\theta _{EY}}}\\ {{\lambda _{KX}}}&{}{{\lambda _{KY}}{\sigma _{UKY}}}&{}{ - {A_3}}&{}0\\ 0&{}{{\sigma _{UEY}}}&{}0&{}{ - {\sigma _{UEY}}} \end{array}} \right) \left( {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {{{{\hat{w}}}_S}}\\ {{{{\hat{w}}}_U}}\\ {{\hat{r}}}\\ {{\hat{\rho }} } \end{array}} \right) = - \left( {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} { - {\alpha _E}}\\ {{\varepsilon _U}{\theta _{UY}}}\\ 0\\ { - 1} \end{array}} \right) {\hat{E}}, \end{aligned}$$

where \({A_2} = {\alpha _E} + {\alpha _K} + {\alpha _U}\), and \({A_3} = {\lambda _{KX}} + {\lambda _{KY}}{\sigma _{UKY}}\).

By solving the above equation, we can obtain:

$$\begin{aligned}{} & {} \frac{{{{{\hat{w}}}_S}}}{{{\hat{E}}}} = {\theta _{UY}}\left[ {{g_1}\left( {{\sigma _{UEY}}} \right) - {\varepsilon _U}} \right] , \\{} & {} \frac{{{{{\hat{w}}}_U}}}{{{\hat{E}}}} = {\theta _{UY}}\left[ {{g_2}\left( {{\sigma _{UEY}}} \right) - {\varepsilon _U}} \right] , \end{aligned}$$

where \(g_1( \sigma _{UEY} ) = \frac{\alpha _E[ ( \theta _{EY} + \theta _{UY} )\lambda _{KX} + \lambda _{KY}\sigma _{UKY} ]}{\theta _{UY}\Delta _2}\sigma _{UEY} + C_1\), \({g_2}\left( {{\sigma _{UEY}}} \right) = - \frac{{{\alpha _E}{\theta _{KY}}{\lambda _{KX}}}}{{{\theta _{UY}}{\Delta _2}}}{\sigma _{UEY}} + {C_2}\), \(\Delta _2 = \sigma _{UEY}[ ( \alpha _E + \alpha _U )\lambda _{KX} + A_2 \lambda _{KY}\sigma _{UKY} ]\), \(C_1 = \frac{1}{\theta _{UY}\Delta _2}\{ ( \alpha _U\theta _{EY} - \alpha _E\theta _{UY} )\lambda _{KX} + [ ( {\alpha _K} + {\alpha _U} )\theta _{EY} - \alpha _E( \theta _{KY} + \theta _{UY} ) ]\lambda _{KY}\sigma _{UKY} \}\), and \(C_2 = \frac{1}{\theta _{UY}\Delta _2}\{ [ ( \alpha _E + \alpha _U )\theta _{EY} + \alpha _E\theta _{KY} ]\lambda _{KX} + A_2 \theta _{EY}\lambda _{KY}\sigma _{UKY} \}\).

Wage inequality can be expressed by:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{{{{\hat{w}}}_S} - {{{\hat{w}}}_U}}}{{{\hat{E}}}}&= {\theta _{UY}}\left[ {{g_1}\left( {{\sigma _{UEY}}} \right) - {g_2}\left( {{\sigma _{UEY}}} \right) } \right] \nonumber \\ {}&= \frac{{{\alpha _E} A_3}}{{{\Delta _2}}}\left( {{\sigma _{UEY}} - 1} \right) . \end{aligned}$$
(A.1)

The implications of stricter pollution control on the skilled wage rate, the unskilled wage rate, and wage inequality are summarized as follows:

  1. 1.

    When \({\sigma _{UEY}} > 1\), we have \(\frac{{{{{\hat{w}}}_S} - {{{\hat{w}}}_U}}}{{{\hat{E}}}} > 0\). Since \({g_1}\left( {{\sigma _{UEY}}} \right) > {g_2}\left( {{\sigma _{UEY}}} \right)\), we also have:

    1. (a)

      If \({\varepsilon _U} < {g_2}\left( {{\sigma _{UEY}}} \right)\), then \(\frac{{{{{\hat{w}}}_S}}}{{{\hat{E}}}} > 0\), and \(\frac{{{{{\hat{w}}}_U}}}{{{\hat{E}}}} > 0\).

    2. (b)

      If \({g_2}\left( {{\sigma _{UEY}}} \right)< {\varepsilon _U} < {g_1}\left( {{\sigma _{UEY}}} \right)\), then \(\frac{{{{{\hat{w}}}_S}}}{{{\hat{E}}}} > 0\), and \(\frac{{{{{\hat{w}}}_U}}}{{{\hat{E}}}} < 0\).

    3. (c)

      If \({\varepsilon _U} > {g_1}\left( {{\sigma _{UEY}}} \right)\), then \(\frac{{{{{\hat{w}}}_S}}}{{{\hat{E}}}} < 0\), and \(\frac{{{{{\hat{w}}}_U}}}{{{\hat{E}}}} < 0\).

  2. 2.

    When \({\sigma _{UEY}} < 1\), we have \(\frac{{{{{\hat{w}}}_S} - {{{\hat{w}}}_U}}}{{{\hat{E}}}} < 0\). Since \({g_1}\left( {{\sigma _{UEY}}} \right) < {g_2}\left( {{\sigma _{UEY}}} \right)\), we also have:

    1. (a)

      If \({\varepsilon _U} < {g_1}\left( {{\sigma _{UEY}}} \right)\), then \(\frac{{{{{\hat{w}}}_S}}}{{{\hat{E}}}} > 0\), and \(\frac{{{{{\hat{w}}}_U}}}{{{\hat{E}}}} > 0\).

    2. (b)

      If \({g_1}\left( {{\sigma _{UEY}}} \right)< {\varepsilon _U} < {g_2}\left( {{\sigma _{UEY}}} \right)\), then \(\frac{{{{{\hat{w}}}_S}}}{{{\hat{E}}}} < 0\), and \(\frac{{{{{\hat{w}}}_U}}}{{{\hat{E}}}} > 0\).

    3. (c)

      If \({\varepsilon _U} > {g_2}\left( {{\sigma _{UEY}}} \right)\), then \(\frac{{{{{\hat{w}}}_S}}}{{{\hat{E}}}} < 0\), and \(\frac{{{{{\hat{w}}}_U}}}{{{\hat{E}}}} < 0\).

\(\square\)

Appendix B: Extension

In this appendix, we extend the model presented in Sect. 3 by assuming the production function of the non-polluting skilled firm is \(x=F(ul,k)\), where u is skilled worker productivity, \(u^\prime (E)<0\), l is skilled labor input, k is capital input, and F(.) satisfies strict quasi-concavity and linear homogeneity. In other words, we maintain consistency with the basic model in terms of the production function. We also need to assume that there is no fixed cost, and the number of firms is given. Otherwise, maintaining free entry would contradict the assumption of constant returns to scale. In this extension, we find that both Propositions 2 and 3 may still hold.

Specifically, Eq. (18) now becomes:

$$\begin{aligned} p\left( {1 - \frac{1}{\sigma }} \right) = {a_{SX}}{w_S} + {a_{KX}}r. \end{aligned}$$

The price p is still endogenously determined by Eq. (19), but the profit \(\Pi\) is not zero, which is calculated as:

$$\begin{aligned} \mathrm{{\Pi }} = \left[ {p - \left( {{a_{SX}}{w_S} + {a_{KX}}r} \right) } \right] X = \frac{\left( {{a_{SX}}{w_S} + {a_{KX}}r} \right) X}{ {\sigma - 1} }. \end{aligned}$$

Equations (4), (9)–(12) still hold, with \(X=nx\). By solving for the new economic system, we have the matrix as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \left( {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} B&{}{ - {\alpha _U}}&{}{ - {\beta _K}}&{}{ - {\alpha _E}}\\ 0&{}{{\theta _{UY}}}&{}{{\theta _{KY}}}&{}{{\theta _{EY}}}\\ {{\lambda _{KX}}{\sigma _{SKX}}}&{}{{\lambda _{KY}}{\sigma _{UKY}}}&{}{ - {A_1}}&{}0\\ 0&{}{{\sigma _{UEY}}}&{}0&{}{ - {\sigma _{UEY}}} \end{array}} \right) \left( {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {{{{\hat{w}}}_S}}\\ {{{{\hat{w}}}_U}}\\ {{\hat{r}}}\\ {{\hat{\rho }} } \end{array}} \right) = \left( {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {{\alpha _E}}\\ { - {\varepsilon _U}{\theta _{UY}}}\\ 0\\ 1 \end{array}} \right) {\hat{E}}, \end{aligned}$$
(B.1)

where \(B = \left( {1 - {\alpha _P}} \right) \left( {{\theta _{SX}} + {\theta _{KX}}{\sigma _{SKX}}} \right) - {\alpha _S}\), \({\beta _K} = {\alpha _K} + \left( {1 - {\alpha _P}} \right) \left( {{\sigma _{SKX}} - 1} \right) {\theta _{KX}}\), and \(\alpha _P\) is the ratio of profits to total income. The determinant of the coefficient matrix can be calculated as \({\Delta _3} = {\sigma _{UEY}}\left[ {B{\lambda _{KY}}{\sigma _{UKY}} + \left( {{\alpha _E} + {\alpha _U}} \right) {\lambda _{KX}}{\sigma _{SKX}}} \right]\). Wage inequality can be expressed by:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{{{{\hat{w}}}_S} - {{{\hat{w}}}_U}}}{{{\hat{E}}}} = \frac{{{\alpha _E}{A_1}}}{{{\Delta _3}}}\left( {{\sigma _{UEY}} - 1} \right) , \end{aligned}$$

which is almost the same as Eq. (A.1) presented in Proof of Proposition 3.

Therefore, we can conclude that Proposition 3 can likely hold when skilled firms adopt constant returns to scale technologies but compete imperfectly. Moreover, since \(\varepsilon _S\) does not enter Eq. (B.1), pollution control does not impact the skilled wage rate via the skilled worker productivity channel, and thus, Proposition 2 can also likely hold.

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Zhang, P. Pollution control, worker productivity, and wage inequality. Ann Reg Sci 72, 1105–1128 (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00168-023-01237-y

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00168-023-01237-y

JEL Classification

Navigation