Skip to main content
Log in

Intellectual property, complex externalities, and the knowledge commons

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Intellectual property (IP) can internalize positive externalities associated with the creation and discovery of ideas, thereby increasing investment in efforts to create and discover ideas. However, IP law also causes negative externalities. Strict IP rights raise the transaction costs associated with consuming and building on existing ideas. This causes a tragedy of the anticommons, in which valuable resources are underused and underdeveloped. By disincentivizing creative projects that build on existing ideas, IP protection, even if it increases original innovation, can inadvertently reduce the rate of iterative innovation. The net effect of IP law on innovation and welfare depends on the relative magnitude of these positive and negative externalities. We argue that the current regime probably suffers from excessive, and excessively rigid, IP protection. This motivates the search for institutional alternatives and complements. We suggest that a monocentric IP rights regime may not be the only, or the most efficient, way to internalize the positive externalities of innovation. The knowledge economy supports the emergence of diverse, polycentric forms of bottom-up self-governance, both market and community led, that entail the citizen coproduction of the norms and practices of intellectual creation and discovery.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The early British understanding of intellectual property rights, as discussed by Blackstone (2016, p. 276), viewed them as “royal patents of privilege” which grant producers “monopolies … by virtue of which a temporary property becomes vested” in the owner of the patent or copyright. The modern recognition of IP, in the form of “the right, which an author may be supposed to have in his own original literary compositions” (Blackstone 2016, p. 274), although it can appeal to support in some aspects of Roman and Common Law, thus came to full maturity in the top-down legislative context of “the statute of monopolies (…) which allows a royal patent of privilege to be granted for fourteen years to any inventor of a new manufacture, for the sole working or making of the same; by virtue whereof a temporary property becomes vested in the patentee” (Blackstone 2016, p. 276).

  2. In addition to this purely consequentialist normative framework, some scholars have argued for and against intellectual property rights on the basis of their impact on justice, fairness, autonomy, dignity, creator rights, and other moral considerations. The ultimate normative and public justification for the legitimate scope of IP rights regime must, of course, ultimately tackle the non-consequentialist dimensions of the IP regime, including the authors’ and creators’ rights perspectives. However, we have purposefully bracketed this dimension out of our analysis in order to better focus on unsettled questions in the IP externalities and innovation debate.

  3. Interestingly, Mossoff (2007, p. 1012) sees a historically salient development, or progress, from “English royal monopoly privileges” to the more property-like “American patent law.” He contrasts the latter favorably to the former.

  4. A “contribution good” resembles a club good (Buchanan 1965) in that it is non-rival but excludable. Kealey and Ricketts (2014, pp. 1015-1016) discuss the relation between these concepts.

References

  • Abrate, G., & Menozzi, A. (2020). User innovation and network effects: The case of video games. Industrial and Corporate Change, 29(6), 1399–1414.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Adams, R., & McCormick, K. (1987). Private goods, club goods, and public goods as a continuum. Review of Social Economy, 45(2), 192–199.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Akerlof, G. A., Arrow, K. J., Breshanan, T. F., Buchanan, J. M., Coase, R. H., Cohen L. R., Friedman, M., Green J. R., Hahn, R.W., Hazlett, T.W., Hemphill, C. S., Litan, R. E., Noll, R. C., Schmalensee, R., Shavell, S., Varian, H. R., & Zeckhauser, R. J. (May 20, 2002). The Copyright Term Extension Act of 1998: An economic analysis. (Amici curiae brief in Eldred v. Ashcroft.) AEI Brookings Center for Regulatory Studies. https://www.brookings.edu/research/the-copyright-term-extension-act-of-1998-an-economic-analysis/.

  • Allen, D. W. E., & Potts, J. (2016). How innovation commons contribute to discovering and developing new technologies. International Journal of the Commons, 10(2), 1035–1054.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. J. (1962). Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention. In R. R. Nelson (Ed.),The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity: Economic and Social Factors (pp. 609-28). Princeton University. Press.

  • Baumol, W. J. (2001). When is inter-firm coordination beneficial? The case of innovation. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 19(5), 727–737.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bell, T. W. (2003). Author’s welfare: Copyright as a statutory mechanism for redistributing rights. Brooklyn Law Review, 69(1), 229–272.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bell, T. W. (2018). Intellectual privilege: Copyright, common law, and the common good. Berlin: Mercatus Center.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blackstone, W. (2016). Commentaries on the laws of England. In S. Stern (Ed.), Book II: Of the rights of things. Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boldrin, M., & Levine, D. (2008). Against intellectual monopoly. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Boldrin, M., & Levine, D. (2009). Intellectual property rights and economic growth in the long run. The American Economic Review, 99(2), 337–342.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breyer, S. (1970). The uneasy case for copyright: A study of copyright in books, photocopies, and computer programs. Harvard Law Review, 84(2), 281–351.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breyer, S. (2010). The uneasy case for copyright: A look back across four decades. The George Washington Law Review, 79, 1635–1643.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buccafusco, C., & Sprigman, C. (2010). Valuing intellectual property: An experiment. Cornell Law Review, 96(1), 1–46.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buccafusco, C., & Sprigman, C. (2011). The creativity effect. The University of Chicago Law Review, 78, 31–52.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1965). An economic theory of clubs. Economica, 32(125), 1–14.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Yong, J. Y. (2000). Symmetric tragedies: Commons and anticommons. Journal of Law and Economics, 43(1), 1–14.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carlson, S. C. (1999). Patent pools and the antitrust dilemma. Yale Journal on Regulation, 16(2), 359–399.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carlisle, K., & Gruby, R. L. (2019). Polycentric systems of governance: A theoretical model for the commons. Policy Studies Journal, 47, 927–952. https://doi.org/10.1111/psj.12212

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choi, J. P. (2010). Patent pools and cross-licensing in the shadow of patent litigation. International Economic Review, 51(2), 441–460.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (1960). The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics, 3, 1–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cowen, T. (1985). Public goods definitions and their institutional context: A critique of public goods theory. Review of Social Economy, 43(1), 53–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coyne, C. J. & Goodman, N. P. (2020). Polycentric Defense. The Independent Review, 25(2), 279-292.

  • Dekker, E., & Kuchař, P. (Eds.). (2022). Governing markets as knowledge commons. Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dekker, E. & Kuchař, P. (forthcoming). Markets and knowledge commons: Is there a difference between private and community governance of markets? Public Choice.

  • Demsetz, H. (1967). Toward a theory of property rights. The American Economic Review, 57(2), 347–359.

    Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz, H. (1996). The core disagreement between Pigou, the profession, and Coase in the analyses of the externality question. European Journal of Political Economy, 12(4), 565–579.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Depoorter, B., & Menell, P. S. (Eds.). (2019). Research handbook on the economics of intellectual property law. Volume 1: Theory. Edward Elgar

  • Depoorter, B., Menell, P. S., & Schwartz, D. L. (Eds.). (2019). Research handbook on the economics of intellectual property law. Volume 2: Analytical methods. Edward Elgar.

  • Devereaux, C., Lawrence, R. Z. & Watkins, M. (2006). Trade-related aspects of intellectual property rights. In Case studies in US trade negotiation: Making the rules (pp. 37–129). Institute for International Economics.

  • Dopfer, K., Foster, J., & Potts, J. (2004). Micro-meso-macro. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 14, 263–279.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dourado, E., & Tabarrok, A. (2015). Public choice perspectives on intellectual property. Public Choice, 163(1/2), 129–151.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drahos, P. (1996). Global law reform and rent-seeking: The case of intellectual property. Australian Journal of Corporate Law, 7, 1–17.

    Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, R. A. (2001). Intellectual property: Old boundaries and new frontiers. Indiana Law Journal, 76(4), 803–827.

    Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, R. A. (2005). Liberty versus property: Cracks in the foundations of copyright law. San Diego Law Review, 42(1), 1–28.

    Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, R. A. (2006). The structural unity of real and intellectual property. Progress on Point, 13(24), 1–11.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frischmann, B., Madison, M. J., & Strandburg, K. J. (Eds.). (2014). Governing knowledge commons. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gilbert, R. J. (2004). Antitrust for patent pools: A century of policy evolution. Stanford Technology Law Review, 3. http://stlr.stanford.edu/STLR/Articles/04_STLR_3

  • Haber, S. H., & Lamoreaux, N. R. (Eds.). (2021). The battle over patents: History and politics of innovation. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, B., Helmers, C., Rogers, M., & Sena, V. (2014). The choice between formal and informal intellectual property: A review. Journal of Economic Literature, 52(2), 375–423.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrison, J. L. (2005). A positive externalities approach to copyright law: Theory and application. Journal of Intellectual Property Law, 13(1), 1–59.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (2011). The constitution of liberty: The definitive edition. (The collected works of F.A. Hayek, vol. XVII). University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Henry, M. D., & Turner, J. L. (2006). The court of appeals for the federal circuit’s impact on patent litigation. The Journal of Legal Studies, 55(1), 85–117.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heller, M. A. (1998). The tragedy of the anticommons: Property in the transition from Marx to markets. Harvard Law Review, 111(3), 621–688.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heller, M. A. (2008). Gridlock economy: How too much ownership wrecks markets, stops innovation, and costs lives. Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heller, M. A., & Eisenberg, R. S. (1998). Can patents deter innovation? The Anticommons in Biomedical Research. Science, 280(5364), 698–701.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hess, C., & Ostrom, E. (Eds.). (2007). Understanding knowledge as a Commons: From theory to practice. The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kealey, T. (1996). The economic laws of scientific research. Palgrave Macmillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kealey, T., & Ricketts, M. (2014). Modelling science as a contribution good. Research Policy, 43(6), 1014–1024.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kealey, T., & Ricketts, M. (2022). The contribution good as the foundation of the industrial revolution. In E. Dekker & P. Kuchař (Eds.), Governing markets as knowledge commons (pp. 19–57). Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kinsella, S. (2008). Against intellectual property. Mises Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Koch, S., & Artmayr, P. (2019). Stability and development of user innovation strategies for video game producers. European Journal of Innovation Management, 23(5), 753–764.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kyle, M. K. (2020). The alignment of innovation policy and social welfare: Evidence from pharmaceuticals. Innovation Policy and the Economy, 20, 95–123.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landes, W. M., & Posner, R. A. (1989). The economic analysis of copyright law. Journal of Legal Studies, XVII, I(2), 325–363.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landes, W. M., & Posner, R. A. (2004). The economic structure of intellectual property law. Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Landry, T. K. (1994). Certainty and discretion in patent law: The on sale bar, the doctrine of equivalents, and judicial power in the federal circuit. Southern California Law Review, 67, 1151–1214.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. (2016). Pirates, prisoners, and preliterates: Anarchic context and the private enforcement of law. European Journal of Law & Economics, 37, 365–379.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lehto, O. (2022). Complex adaptation and permissionless innovation: An evolutionary approach to universal basic income. (Doctoral thesis.) King’s College London, U.K. https://kclpure.kcl.ac.uk/portal/en/studentTheses/complex-adaptation-and-permissionless-innovation

  • Lessig, L. (2001). The future of ideas: The fate of the commons in a connected world. Random House.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lessig, L. (2004). Free culture: How big media uses technology and the law to lock down culture and control creativity. Penguin Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Machlup, F., & Penrose, E. (1950). The patent controversy in the nineteenth century. The Journal of Economic History, 10(1), 1–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Machlup, F. (1958). An economic review of the patent system. (Study no. 15. Study of the subcommittee on patents, trademarks and copyrights of the committee on the judiciary, United States Senate, 85th Congress, second session.) Government Printing Office.

  • Madison, M. J., Frischmann, B. M., & Strandburg, K. J. (2010). Constructing commons in the cultural Environment. Cornell Law Review, 95(4), 657–710.

    Google Scholar 

  • Martin, A. (2013). Abolition as a positive program: A Hayekian perspective on intellectual property. What would Hayek say today (really)? (pp. 33–35). The Legatum Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Martin, A. (2015). Degenerate cosmopolitanism. Social Philosophy & Policy, 32(1), 74–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCloskey, D. (2010). Bourgeois dignity: Why economics can’t explain the modern world. University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • McGinnis, M. D. (1999). Polycentricity and local public economies: Readings from the workshop in political theory and policy analysis. University of Michigan Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Mokyr, J. (2009). Intellectual property rights, the industrial revolution, and the beginnings of modern economic growth. The American Economic Review, 99(2), 349–355.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mokyr, J. (2016). A culture of growth: The origins of the modern economy. Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Mossoff, A. (2005). Is copyright property. San Diego Law Review, 42(1), 29–44.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mossoff, A. (2007). Who cares what Thomas Jefferson thought about patents: Reevaluating the patent ‘privilege’ in historical context. Cornell Law Review, 92(5), 952–1012.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mossoff, A. (2013). Intellectual property and property rights. George Mason Law & Economics Research Paper, 14–31. Edward Elgar.

  • Nelson, R.R. (1959). The Simple Economics of Basic Scientific Research. Journal of Political Economy, 67(3), 297-306.

  • Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: The evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (1996). Crossing the great divide: Coproduction, synergy, and development. World Development, 24(6), 1073–1087.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (2005). Understanding institutional diversity. Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (2010). The challenge of self-governance in complex contemporary environments. The Journal of Speculative Philosophy, 24(4), 316–332.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (2012). Nested externalities and polycentric institutions: Must we wait for global solutions to climate change before taking actions at other scales? Economic Theory, 49(2), 353–369.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E., Janssen, M. A., & Anderies, J. M. (2007). Going beyond panaceas. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 104(39), 15176–15178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E., Parks, R., & Whitaker, G. (1973). Do we really want to consolidate urban police forces? Public Administration Review, 33, 423–433.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E., & Whitaker, G. (1974). Community control and governmental responsiveness: The case of police in black neighborhoods. In W. D. Hawley & D. Rogers (Eds.), Improving the quality of urban management (pp. 303–334). Sage Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, V., Tiebout, V., & Warren, R. (1961). The organization of government in metropolitan areas: A theoretical inquiry”. The American Political Science Review, 55(4), 831–842.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Palmer, T. G. (1989). Intellectual property: A non-Posnerian law and economics approach. Hamline Law Review, 12(2), 261–304.

    Google Scholar 

  • Paniagua, P., & Rayamajhee, V. (2021). A polycentric approach for pandemic governance: Nested externalities and co-production challenges. Journal of Institutional Economics, 18(4), 537–552.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Paniagua, P., & Rayamajhee, V. (2023). On the nature and structure of externalities. Public Choice. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-023-01098-1

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Papandreou, A. A. (1998). Externality and institutions. Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Posner, R. (2005). Intellectual property: The law and economics approach. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19(2), 57–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Potts, J. (2019). Innovation commons. Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Potts, J., Harhoff, D., Torrance, A., & von Hippel, E. (2021). Social welfare gains from innovation commons: Theory, evidence, and policy implications. (September 2, 2021). https://ssrn.com/abstract=3915997.

  • Ridley, M. (2020). How innovation works: And why it flourishes in freedom. Harper Collins.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, P. (1990). Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5), S71–S102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Raymond, E. (1999). The cathedral and the bazaar. (Revised and expanded). O’Reilly.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. (1954). The pure theory of public expenditure. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 36(4), 387–389.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schweik, C. M. (2014). Toward the comparison of open source commons institutions. In B. M. Frischmann, M. J. Madison, & K. J. Strandburg (Eds.), Governing knowledge commons (pp. 255–280). Oxford University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Schweik, C. M., & English, R. C. (2012). Internet success: A study of open-source software commons. MIT Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A., Atkisson, C., & Schweik, C. (2022). Cui bono: Do open source software incubator policies and procedures benefit the projects or the incubator? International Journal of the Commons, 16(1), 64–77. https://doi.org/10.5334/ijc.1176

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro, C. (2001). Navigating the patent thicket: Cross licenses, patent pools, and standard setting. In A. B. Jaffe, J. Lerner, & S. Stern (Eds.), Innovation policy and the economy (pp. 119–150). MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shughart, W. F., & Thomas, D. W. (2016). Intellectual property rights, public choice, networks, and the new age of informal IP regimes. Supreme Court Economic Review, 23, 169–192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Slobodian, Q. (2020). The law of the sea of ignorance: F. A. Hayek, Fritz Machlup, and other neoliberals confront the intellectual property problem. In D. Plehwe, Q. Slobodian, & P. Mirowski (Eds.), Nine lives of neoliberalism (pp. 70–91). Verso.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, V. (2008). Rationality in economics: Constructivist and ecological forms. Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Spulber, D. (2021). The case for patents. World Scientific Publishing.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Stallman, R. (2006). Did you say ‘intellectual property’? It’s a seductive mirage. Policy Futures in Education, 4(4), 334–336.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J. E. (2008). Economic foundations of intellectual property rights. Duke Law Journal, 57, 1693–1724.

    Google Scholar 

  • Strandburg, K., Csárdi, G., Tobochnik, J., et al. (2006). Law and the science of networks: An overview and an application to the ‘patent explosion.’ Berkeley Technology Law Journal, 21(4), 1293–1362.

    Google Scholar 

  • Strandburg, K. (2008). Users as innovators: Implications for patent doctrine. University of Colorado Law Review, 79(2), 467–544.

    Google Scholar 

  • Teece, D. J. (2011). Favoring dynamic over static competition: Implications for antitrust analysis and policy. In G. A. Manne & J. D. Wright (Eds.), Competition policy and patent law under uncertainty (pp. 204–227). Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vaidhyanathan, S. (2001). Copyrights and copywrongs: The rise of intellectual property and how it threatens creativity. New York University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • von Hippel, E. (2005). Democratizing innovation. MIT Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • von Hippel, E. (2017). Free innovation. MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Watkins, W. J. (2013). Patent trolls: Predatory litigation and the smothering of innovation. Independent Institute.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Otto Lehto.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors did not receive support from any organization for the submitted work. The authors have no relevant financial or non-financial interests, or other conflicts of interest, to disclose.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Goodman, N., Lehto, O. Intellectual property, complex externalities, and the knowledge commons. Public Choice (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-023-01110-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-023-01110-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation