Skip to main content
Log in

Regulatory capture in a resource boom

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

States oversee most regulation of oil and gas extraction in the United States. When relying on regulation, state oil and gas agencies may be susceptible to capture by firms developing resources. This may be particularly problematic during booms of resource development when information asymmetries are largest and existing regulations risk becoming obsolete. If regulators are captured, they may take actions that serve concentrated private interests in preference to the public interests they are charged with upholding. I develop and test hypotheses that oil and gas regulators are captured. The primary empirical tests use data from state regulation in North Dakota to prevent resource waste by restricting natural gas flaring. The empirical results are consistent with the theory of regulatory capture, providing empirical evidence that captured regulators serve well-organized specific interests in preference to diffuse general interests. These results provide novel granular evidence of the mechanisms for regulatory capture by showing differences in regulatory responses across firms and locations. This detailed evidence has implications for the design of regulations and reliance on regulatory interventions to protect the public interest.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Dyer (2016) for an in-depth study in Colorado and Brasier et al. (2011) for additional examples. Collins and Nkansah (2015) and Maguire and Winters (2017) also provide additional supporting evidence of dissatisfaction with the course of development.

  2. Articulation of these models for economics is widely attributed to Stigler (1971), with further contributions by Posner (1974) and Peltzman (1976). Dal Bó (2006) provides a valuable summary of the extensive literature on regulatory capture.

  3. These data are dawn from BEA series SAGDP2N, reporting state-level GDP by industry classification on an annual basis.

  4. As reported by EIA crude oil production (not including lease condensate) at the state-year level.

  5. Drawn from BLS statewide summaries for North Dakota.

  6. Gas capture plans have been required for new wells since 2015. While the rollout of this new regulatory instrument has been delayed from initial plans (to 2019 from 2017), for the purposes of the empirical analysis I only use the pre-period to keep the structure consistent. Lade and Rudik (2020) study gas capture plans that were implemented after 2015 and conclude that they have been effective in reducing flaring.

  7. Because the transactions costs of monitoring development activity are relatively high, regulations may be preferable on efficiency grounds to decentralized monitoring and enforcement.

  8. The exception to this rule arises in a case with large negative spillovers from production and a regulator placing a high weight on public welfare.

  9. Employment gains have been a focus of considerable research effort. See Allcott and Keniston (2018), Feyrer et al. (2017), Fleming et al. (2015), Komarek (2016), Kelsey et al. (2016), Marchand and Weber (2018), Maniloff and Mastromonaco (2017), Jacobsen (2019).

  10. Appendix A details this decision for operators.

  11. Only one field in North Dakota has this problem, and the wells in that field do not access the Bakken shale.

  12. This language can be found at NDCC §38-08-01.

  13. See NDCC §38-08-06.4. For comparison, during the period of this study in Texas, flaring was generally restricted to 10 days. See TAC 16-1-3 §3.32 for the relevant Texas code. Less than 1% of produced gas was flared in Texas, though the fraction has quadrupled in recent years. For further discussion of the situation in Texas, particularly the Eagle Ford, see Wells (2014). Similarly, neighboring Montana has a much tighter temporal restriction on flaring than does North Dakota. Wells can flare gas for the first 60 days of production, but then to continue must receive an exemption from the Board of Oil and Gas Conservation. For more on the differences between North Dakota and Montana, see Lange and Redlinger (2019).

  14. Cf. the flaring rules in neighboring Montana (sharing the Bakken formation), which are based on natural gas production, not co-produced oil. In Montana, if a well averages more than 100 Mcf/day, it must have a Board of Oil and Gas (Montana analogue to NDIC Oil and Gas Division) exemption to continue flaring (ARM §36-22-1220, as granted by MCA §82-11-124). Even with an exemption, payment is due on severance tax and royalty.

  15. Because the data are self-reported, the issue of whether reports are truthful is pertinent. Reporting is required under NDCC §38-12-02-1(c). Penalties for fraudulent reporting are outlined in NDCC §38-08-16.

  16. If firms violate field rules, they are subject to sanctions specified in NDCC §38-08-16. Civil penalties are not to exceed $12,500 per offense; criminal penalties are allowed that permit charging individuals with a felony.

  17. This lack of enforcement activity was confirmed by Alison Ritter, NDIC Public Information Officer, 24 October 2016.

  18. Anderson et al. (2018) demonstrate limited price response on the intensive production margin, with far greater response in terms of the pace of drilling. The pace of drilling is one possible measure of the resource boom, while cumulative production is another. The two are linked through the firm-level financing constraint, which is not specified here.

  19. For simplicity we ignore the cases in which investment D is not made, and the case in which D is made but \(I_1=I_2=0\). By assumption that \(I_1\)=0, the two cases do not differ.

  20. This condition is analogous to condition (A3) in Kuller and Cummings (1974) when the objective function is (A12) rather than (10). The possibility of cost spillovers, e.g., two operators sharing a gathering network or installed capacity in a gas processing plant, alters (A.3) by effectively reducing \(I_2\) for an individual firm.

  21. As the time steps in the discrete time process become shorter, the values of the discrete time process approach those of a continuous process. The physical decline in the discrete time tree is analogous to a negative drift in the continuous time setting. This shortens the relevant exercise window and increases the continuation region, in which flaring continues indefinitely, albeit at reduced amounts each month.

  22. This uncertainty is compound of the uncertainty over future prices, the decline rate, and changes in connection costs.

References

  • Ajugwo, A. O. (2013). Negative effects of gas flaring: The Nigerian experience. Journal of Environment Pollution and Human Health, 1(1), 6–8.

    Google Scholar 

  • Allcott, H., & Keniston, D. (2018). Dutch disease or agglomeration? The local economic effects of natural resource booms in modern America. The Review of Economic Studies, 85(2), 695–731.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, S. T., Kellogg, R., & Salant, S. W. (2018). Hotelling under pressure. Journal of Political Economy, 126(3), 984–1026.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asibor, E., Marongiu-Porcu, M., & Economides, M. J. (2013). Oil production optimization without natural gas constraints: The harvesting of upstream natural gas. Journal of Natural Gas Science and Engineering, 15, 59–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1983). A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98(3), 371–400.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. (1986). The public interest hypothesis revisited: A new test of Peltzman’s theory of regulation. Public Choice, 49(3), 223–234.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell, W., & Kokoza, A. (2022). Natural gas flaring, respiratory health, and distributional effects. Journal of Public Economics, 208, 104601.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dal Bó, E. (2006). Regulatory capture: a review. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 22(2), 203–225.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyce, J. R. (1998). Rent-seeking in natural resource quota allocations. Public Choice, 96(3–4), 271–294.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bradley, R. L. (1996). Oil, gas & government: The US experience (Vol. 2). Rowman & Littlefield Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brasier, K. J., Filteau, M. R., McLaughlin, D. K., Jacquet, J., Stedman, R. C., Kelsey, T. W., & Goetz, S. J. (2011). Residents perceptions of community and environmental impacts from development of natural gas in the Marcellus shale: A comparison of Pennsylvania and New York cases. Journal of Rural Social Sciences, 26(1), 32.

    Google Scholar 

  • Calel, R., & Mahdavi, P. (2020). The unintended consequences of antiflaring policies-and measures for mitigation. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 117(23), 12503–12507.

    Article  CAS  ADS  Google Scholar 

  • Chermak, J. M. (1996). The economic possibilities of natural gas conservation: Antithetical results of prorationing regulation. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 10, 147–163.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Collins, A. R., & Nkansah, K. (2015). Divided rights, expanded conflict: The impact of split estates in natural gas production. Land Economics, 91(4), 688–703.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooper, J. C., & Kovacic, W. E. (2012). Behavioral economics: Implications for regulatory behavior. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 41, 41–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Costello, C., & Grainger, C. A. (2018). Property rights, regulatory capture, and exploitation of natural resources. Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists, 5(2), 441–479.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox, J. C., Ross, S. A., & Rubinstein, M. (1979). Option pricing: A simplified approach. Journal of Financial Economics, 7(3), 229–263.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Duflo, E., Greenstone, M., Pande, R., & Ryan, N. (2018). The value of regulatory discretion: Estimates from environmental inspections in India. Econometrica, 86(6), 2123–2160.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dyer, J. (2016). Behind closed doors. Boulder Weekly. https://boulderweekly.com/news/behind-closed-doors-2/

  • Ehrman, M. U. (2014). Lights out in the bakken: A review and analysis of flaring regulation and its potential effect on North Dakota shale oil production. W. Virginia Law Review, 117, 549–591.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feyrer, J., Mansur, E. T., & Sacerdote, B. (2017). Geographic dispersion of economic shocks: Evidence from the fracking revolution. The American Economic Review, 107(4), 1313–1334.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fitzgerald, T. (2018). Regulatory obsolescence through technological change in oil and gas extraction. Wm. & Mary Envtl. L. & Pol’y Rev., 43, 137.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fitzgerald, T., & Stiglbauer, C. (2015). Flaring of associated natural gas in the bakken shale. Working Paper. Texas Tech University.

  • Fleming, D., Komarek, T., Partridge, M., & Measham, T. (2015). The booming socioeconomic impacts of shale: A review of findings and methods in the empirical literature. Working Paper 68487, MPRA.

  • Gold, R. (2014). The boom: how fracking ignited the American energy revolution and changed the world. Simon and Schuster.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harrington, W. (1988). Enforcement leverage when penalties are restricted. Journal of Public Economics, 37(1), 29–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heyes, A., & Rickman, N. (1999). Regulatory dealing—revisiting the Harrington paradox. Journal of Public Economics, 72(3), 361–378.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jacobsen, G. D. (2019). Who wins in an energy boom? Evidence from wage rates and housing. Economic Inquiry, 57(1), 9–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kang, K. (2016). Policy influence and private returns from lobbying in the energy sector. The Review of Economic Studies, 83(1), 269–305.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Kelsey, T. W., Partridge, M. D., & White, N. E. (2016). Unconventional gas and oil development in the United States: Economic experience and policy issues. Applied Economic Perspectives and Policy, 38(2), 191–214.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Komarek, T. M. (2016). Labor market dynamics and the unconventional natural gas boom: Evidence from the Marcellus region. Resource and Energy Economics, 45, 1–17.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krueger, A. O. (1974). The political economy of the rent-seeking society. The American Economic Review, 64(3), 291–303.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuller, R. G., & Cummings, R. G. (1974). An economic model of production and investment for petroleum reservoirs. American Economic Review, 64(1), 66–79.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lade, G. E., & Rudik, I. (2020). Costs of inefficient regulation: Evidence from the Bakken. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 102, 102336.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lange, I., & Redlinger, M. (2019). Effects of stricter environmental regulations on resource development. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 96, 60–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levine, M. E., & Forrence, J. L. (1990). Regulatory capture, public interest, and the public agenda: Toward a synthesis. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 6, 167–198.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Libecap, G. D., & Wiggins, S. N. (1984). Contractual responses to the common pool: Prorationing of crude oil production. American Economic Review, 74(1), 87–98.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maguire, K., & Winters, J. V. (2017). Energy boom and gloom? Local effects of oil and natural gas drilling on subjective well-being. Growth and Change, 48(4), 590–610.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maniloff, P., & Mastromonaco, R. (2017). The local employment impacts of fracking: A national study. Resource and Energy Economics, 49, 62–85.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marchand, J., & Weber, J. (2018). Local labor markets and natural resources: A synthesis of the literature. Journal of Economic Surveys, 32(2), 469–490.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marks, L. (2022). The abatement cost of methane emissions from natural gas production. Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists, 9(2), 165–198.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mason, C. F., & Roberts, G. (2018). Price elasticity of supply and productivity: An analysis of natural gas wells in Wyoming. The Energy Journal. https://doi.org/10.5547/01956574.39.SI1.cmas

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCubbins, M. D., Noll, R. G., & Weingast, B. R. (1987). Administrative procedures as instruments of political control. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 3(2), 243–277.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pearson, C. M., Griffin, L., Wright, C. A., & Weijers, L. (2013). Breaking up is hard to do: Creating hydraulic fracture complexity in the Bakken central basin. In SPE Hydraulic Fracturing Technology Conference, 163827. Society of Petroleum Engineers.

  • Peltzman, S. (1976). Toward a more general theory of regulation. The Journal of Law & Economics, 19(2), 211–248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peltzman, S. (1984). Constituent interest and congressional voting. The Journal of Law and Economics, 27(1), 181–210.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peltzman, S. (2022). “The theory of economic regulation" after 50 years. Public Choice. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-022-00996-0

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Posner, R. A. (1974). Theories of economic regulation. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 5(2), 335–358.

    Google Scholar 

  • Righetti, T. K. (2020). The incidental environmental agency. Utah Law Review, 2020(3), 685–754.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roberts, R. W., & Kurtenbach, J. M. (1998). State regulation and professional accounting educational reforms: An empirical test of regulatory capture theory. Journal of Accounting and Public Policy, 17(3), 209–226.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robinson, J. A., Torvik, R., & Verdier, T. (2006). Political foundations of the resource curse. Journal of Development Economics, 79(2), 447–468.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shimshack, J. P., & Ward, M. B. (2005). Regulator reputation, enforcement, and environmental compliance. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 50(3), 519–540.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Srivastava, U., Oonk, D., Lange, I., & Bazilian, M. (2019). Distributional impacts of the North Dakota gas flaring policy. The Electricity Journal, 32(8), 106630.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. J. (1971). The theory of economic regulation. The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 2, 3–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Walker, G. P. (2019). A regulating and watchful law: Oil and gas conservation law and the North Dakota industrial commission. Oil and Gas, Natural Resources, and Energy Journal, 5(3), 427–458.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wells, B. (2014). Please give us one more oil boom-i promise not to screw it up this time: The broken promise of casinghead gas flaring in the Eagle Ford Shale. Texas Journal of Oil, Gas, and Energy Law, 9(2), 319–355.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Timothy Fitzgerald.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Initial and partial support for this project was provided by a Lone Mountain Fellowship from the Property and Environment Research Center. The author thanks Matt Kelly for access to the North Dakota field rule database. Comments from an anonymous reviewer, Dean Lueck, and Lynne Kiesling, as well as attendees at Baylor University, University of Arizona, USAEE/IAEE North American Conference, AERE Summer Conference, SIOE Annual Conference, NU-CMU Energy Workshop, and Public Choice Society are appreciated.

Supplementary Information

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary file 1 (pdf 87 KB)

Appendices

Appendix

A model of flaring

The first key feature of natural gas flaring in North Dakota is that oil and natural gas are co-produced. Separable investments in gathering and processing capacity are necessary to collect and market oil and natural gas. If these investments are not made, then the gas must be flared thanks to the lack of alternatives. The opportunity cost of flaring is the foregone net benefit of capturing and using the gas. The benefit of flaring is the time value of avoiding a delay in the net value of oil produced.

2.1 Production dynamics

Oil and natural gas production is dynamic. Consider a simple model of the dynamics in which two products decline at the same constant rate. Consider the production of two outputs \(y^1\) and \(y^2\) that are co-produced over time. For each period t:

$$\begin{aligned} {\textbf{y}}_t = \left( 1 - \alpha \right) {\textbf{y}}_{t-1} \end{aligned}$$
(A.1)

which allows us to calculate the ultimate recovery of product i as a function of initial production— \(\frac{{\textbf{y}}_0}{\alpha }\) over an infinite horizon. Cumulative production at any time \(\tau\) is \(\mathbf {y_0} \sum _{t=0}^{\tau } \left( 1 - \alpha \right) ^t\). Estimable parameter \(\alpha\) is interpreted as the average decline rate.

An essential fixed investment \(D>0\) allows joint production of two outputs, \(y_1\) and \(y_2\), which are produced in fixed proportion \(\xi\). After investment D is made, the costs of collecting and marketing the outputs are separable. These costs have both fixed and variable components. Normalize the fixed cost of collecting and marketing \(y_1\) to zero so that the fixed costs of collecting and marketing \(y_2\) are always higher. The firm has two potentially profitable options, depending on which investment option is chosen.Footnote 19

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi = {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} \left( p_1 - c_1 \right) y_1 &{} I_1=1, I_2=0 \\ \left( p_1 - c_1 \right) y_1 + \left( p_2 - c_2 \right) \frac{y_1}{\xi } &{} I_1=1, I_2=1 \\ \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$
(A.2)

In the first case, \(y_1\) is produced and \(y_2\) is freely disposed. In the second case, both products are sold. The choice of whether to pursue free disposal as a strategy depends on the total profits associated with each strategy. Production occurs over time, so the decision to invest at time \(\tau\) is a function of the difference in profits. In the simplest setting, this decision rule requires that the net present value of \(y_2\) must exceed the fixed investment required to collect and market it, taking the time value of money into account via discount factor \(\beta\).

$$\begin{aligned} B_t(I_2; y_{1t} ) = \sum _{t=\tau }^T \left\{ \beta ^t \left( p_{2t} - c_{2t} \right) \frac{y_{1t}}{\xi } \right\} - I_2 \gtrless 0 \end{aligned}$$
(A.3)

This is comparable to previous results when the firm’s investment decision is isolated from spillovers on other firms.Footnote 20

The expected benefits of connection are unlikely to be observed directly. Suppose that the probability that an investment is made to instantaneously connect the well is a monotonically increasing function of the expected gains from connection.

$$\begin{aligned} \textrm{Pr}(I_2=1) = F(B) \end{aligned}$$
(A.4)

The function F satisfies the conditions of a cumulative distribution function.

Comparative statistics on (A.4) yield three empirical predictions. Assuming that well operators are profit maximizers, any increase in the net price of captured gas should decrease flaring. A higher output price makes the flared gas worth more and thus makes connection to the marketing network more likely. Similarly, increasing the cost of free disposal (such as by requiring higher payments for taxes and foregone royalties on flared gas) should increase the probability of connection. Conversely, if the required fixed investment to make a connection is higher, we would expect that operators are less likely to decide to connect.

2.2 Revenue variability

The dynamic nature of the problem also introduces the prospect of \(p_2\) varying over time. Changing the market price for natural gas will likely alter the net benefits from reducing flaring. Suppose that the direction of change in \(p_2\) in any discrete time interval \(\Delta t\) is determined by a binomial distribution: the probability of an upward price movement of magnitude \(\delta\) is \(\rho\), and the probability of downward price movement \(\frac{1}{\delta }\) is \(1-\rho\). This allows for a recombining lattice as described in Cox et al. (1979), which approaches a continuous Weiner process as \(\Delta t\) becomes short. Figure 6 depicts the possible paths for price evolution over time periods. The connection investment is effectively irreversible and specific to a particular well, or group of wells in the case of a gas plant. However, this investment option is different from many similar problems insofar as production declines over time subject to A.1.

The deterministic physical decline is coupled with stochastic prices to modify the left-hand side of (A.3). Revenues in period t are \(y_{t-1}(1 - \alpha ) p_t \delta\) if price increases and as \(\frac{y_{t-1}(1 - \alpha ) p_t}{\delta }\) if price decreases. The straightforward specification allows us to combine price volatility and physical decline to a single measure of revenue volatility. This slightly adjusts the values of the underlying asset at the nodes of Fig. 6. Assuming that the decline rate is positive, this makes waiting to invest in gathering less attractive, and therefore should decrease the value associated with waiting as time progresses.Footnote 21

Fig. 6
figure 6

Binomial price tree for depleting asset

For a given initial production rate \(y_0\), each node can be assigned an expected future revenue and an option value associated with waiting to connect, conditional on expectations about volatility. The expected future revenue can be compared with the investment cost. The investment cost may change over time, for example as an existing gathering network is installed closer to a given well. Represent the option to connect to gathering as a function of the age of the well, the current price level and expected volatility, the current investment cost needed for connection, and the uncertainty about the continuation value of the option.Footnote 22 The value of the option varies with the predetermined initial production level, the underlying remaining revenue (A), and the investment cost (\(I_2\)).

$$\begin{aligned} V(A(t), p_t, I; y_1, T) = {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} \sum _{t=\tau }^T \left\{ \beta ^t \left( \overline{p_{2t} - c_{2t}} \right) \frac{y_t^1}{\xi } \right\} - I_2 &{} \textrm{Exercise }\\ e^{-r}V(A(t+1), p_{t+1}, I_2; y_1, T) &{} \textrm{Cntinuation} \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$
(A.5)

The value of the option is strictly decreasing in the underlying revenue A and I, and increasing in p. The option should be exercised most often for wells that are relatively early in their productive lives, at times when the price is relatively high, and when connection costs are relatively low. The option has a term of the expected economic life, T, but because production deterministically decreases over the life of the well, it is likely to fall in value over time.

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Fitzgerald, T. Regulatory capture in a resource boom. Public Choice 198, 93–127 (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-023-01113-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-023-01113-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation