Skip to main content
Log in

Ethnically asymmetric political representation and the provision of public goods: theory and evidence from Ethiopia

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Economics of Governance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

While the salience of ethnicity as a factor in African politics has been documented in the literature, less is known about its impacts on economic development. Using data from Ethiopia, we study the developmental impacts of ethnically asymmetric political representation. We find that enhanced political representation improves access to public goods. Moreover, regional disparities of access to public goods due to improved political representation are more pronounced in rural than in urban areas. To complement our empirical analysis, we construct a theoretical model that suggests potential mechanisms through which public goods provision favors regions with better political representation.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Acemoglu et al. (2014), Anderson et al. (2015), Banerjee et al. (2005), Banerjee and Somanathan (2007), Khemani (2007), among others.

  2. Ethiopia’s internal political boundaries were redrawn along ethnic lines in 1994 (see Fig. 9 in the Appendix); prior to that, the country was divided into administrative provinces as shown in Fig. 8 in the Appendix.

  3. See e.g. Bardhan and Mookherjee (2006a), Acemoglu and Robinson (2006), Acemoglu (MIT) lecture notes in political economy (Acemoglu xxx).

  4. For a thorough review of the literature on the political economy of decentralization, see Lockwood (2005) and Mookherjee (2015).

  5. For a complete survey of this empirical literature, see Crook and Manor (1998), Treisman (2007), and Khemani (2007).

  6. Mansuri and Rao (2013) provide an excellent overview of most of the empirical studies of the effects of local decentralization using data at the local level.

  7. Alesina and La Ferrara (2005) provide an excellent review of this literature.

  8. The PDOs include the Oromo People’s Democratic Organization (OPDO), the Amhara People’s Democratic Movement (APDM), and the Southern Ethiopian Peoples’ Democratic Movement (SEPDM).

  9. Data from Marshall et al. (2018).

  10. The following link offers evidence for this claim, by showing the distribution of high-ranking army officers in the Ethiopian army under the TPLF/EPRDF. http://www.ginbot7.org/the-total-domination-of-the-ethiopian-army-by-ethnic-tigrean-officers/.

  11. For instance, the largest state in the Ethiopian federation, Oromia, had six presidents—one of whom was killed under unknown circumstances, while two others had to flee the country—during the time period when Meles Zenawi was the sole leader of the TPLF and the country until his death in 2012.

  12. The EPRDF is a a coalition of the so-called Tigray People’s Liberation Front, the Amhara People’s Democratic Front, the Oromo People’s Democratic Organization, and the Southern Ethiopian Peoples’ Democratic Movement.

  13. See Burgess et al. (2015, p. 1818).

  14. This information is based on the analyses of the budgets published by the Federal Ministry of Finance and the regional Bureaus of Finance.

  15. See Roth et al. (2023) for an overview of the new literature on TWFE and DID.

  16. Ethnic favoritism has different manifestations in the literature, such as patronage, targeted public infrastructure projects, and transfer payments (De Luca et al. 2018), all of which revolve around the fact that high-level politicians unilaterally make allocative decisions or choose policies that directly benefit their co-ethnic groups.

  17. See Raleigh et al. (2010).

  18. Intuitively, the fact that \(y_{i_{{t_i}{t_i}}}<0\) may be due to the fact that regions that receive more transfers may find it difficult to find enough new ‘shovel-ready’ infrastructure projects to fund.

  19. The assumption that this cost of revolt in a region decreases when the transfer received from the Center increases is consistent with the literature on fiscal appeasement [see, e.g., Treisman (1996), Ishiyama (2012)]. In particular, Ishiyama (2012) argues that, following the 2005 elections, the Ethiopian central government might have increased federal financial disbursements towards districts that supported the opposition, as an appeasement strategy.

  20. Notice that transfers are not a direct function of the degree of political favoritism: in fact \(t_i(\rho _i)\) would largely amount to assuming the result.

  21. The assumption that output increases with public investments at a decreasing rate is again consistent with the idea that increased government expenditure may have diminishing returns, as they are likely to be financed using resources that may otherwise fund potential investments by the private sector.

  22. Notably, Ethiopia is not in their sample.

  23. This is well-documented in the US State Department’s annual reports in the early 1990s.

  24. In the most recent national election held in 2015, the EPRDF won 100% of the seats in Parliament, beating its own record of 99% in the 2010 elections.

  25. Here is BBC’s documentation of this violent episode: http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/africa/6064638.stm.

  26. See: https://www.amnesty.org/download/Documents/4000/afr250062014en.pdf.

References

  • Acemoglu Daron MIT. Political Economy Lecture Notes.https://economics.mit.edu/files/8753

  • Acemoglu D, Robinson JA (2006) Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy. Cambridge Books. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D, Reed T, Robinson J (2014) Chiefs: economic development and elite control of civil society in Sierra Leone. J Polit Econ 122(2):319–368. https://doi.org/10.1086/674988

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, La Ferrara E (2000) Participation in heterogeneous communities. Q J Econ 115(3):847–904

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, La Ferrara E (2005) Ethnic diversity and economic performance. J Econ Lit 43(3):762–800

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Baqir R, Easterly W (1999) Public goods and ethnic divisions. Q J Econ 114(4):1243–1284

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson S, Francois P, Kotwal A (2015) Clientelism in Indian villages. Am Econ Rev 105(6):1780–1816

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ansolabehere S, Gerber A, Snyder J (2002) Equal votes, equal money: court-ordered redistricting and public expenditures in the American States. Am Polit Sci Rev 96(04):767–777

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Atlas CM et al (1995) Slicing the federal government net spending pie: who wins, who loses, and why. Am Econ Rev 85(3):624–29

    Google Scholar 

  • Banerjee A, Somanathan R (2007) The political economy of public goods: some evidence from India. J Dev Econ 82(2):287–314

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banerjee A, Iyer L, Somanathan R (2005) History, social divisions, and public goods in rural India. J Eur Econ Assoc 3(2–3):639–647

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bardhan P, Mookherjee D (2006) Decentralisation and accountability in infrastructure delivery in developing countries. Econ J 116(508):101–127

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bekele YW, Kjosavik DJ, Shanmugaratnam N (2016) State-society relations in ethiopia: a political-economy perspective of the post-1991 order. Soc Sci 5(3):1–19

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley T, Coate S (2003) Elected versus appointed regulators: theory and evidence. J Eur Econ Assoc 1(5):1176–1206

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boex J, Martinez-Vazquez J (2005) The determinants of the incidence of intergovernmental grants: a survey of the international experience. Public Finance Manag 4(4):454–479

    Google Scholar 

  • Burgess R, Jedwab R, Miguel E, Morjaria A, Padró i Miquel G (2015) The value of democracy: evidence from road building in Kenya. Am Econ Rev 105(6):1817–1851

  • Case A (2001) Election goals and income redistribution: recent evidence from Albania. Eur Econ Rev 45(3):405–423

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chattopadhyay R, Duflo E (2004) Women as policy makers: evidence from a randomized policy experiment in India. Econometrica 72(5):1409–1443

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crook RC, Manor J (1998) Democracy and decentralisation in South Asia and West Africa. Cambridge University Press

  • de Chaisemartin C, D’Haultfoeuille X, Guyonvarch Y (2019) Fuzzy differences-in-differences with Stata. Stata J 19(2):435–458

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterly W, Levine R (1997) Africa’s growth tragedy: policies and ethnic divisions. Q J Econ 112(4):1203–1250

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fan CS, Lin C, Treisman D (2009) Political decentralization and corruption: evidence from around the world. J Public Econ 93(1–2):14–34

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Franck R, Rainer I (2012) Does the leader’s ethnicity matter? Ethnic favoritism, education, and health in Sub-Saharan Africa. Am Polit Sci Rev 106(02):294–325

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Francois P, Rainer I, Trebbi F (2015) How is power shared in Africa? Econometrica 83:465–503. https://doi.org/10.3982/ECTA11237

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Golden M, Min B (2013) Distributive politics around the world. Ann Rev Polit Sci 16:73–99

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman PJ (1994) A political theory of intergovernmental grants. Public Choice 78(3–4):295–303

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Habyarimana J, Humphreys M, Posner DN, Weinstein JM (2007) Why does ethnic diversity undermine public goods provision? Am Polit Sci Rev 101(04):709–725

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henze P (2000) Layers of time: history of Ethiopia. C. Hurst & Co., Publishers

  • Hodler R, Raschky PA (2014) Regional favoritism. Q J Econ 129(2):995–1033

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Inman RP (1987) Federal assistance and local services in the United States: the evolution of a new federalist fiscal order. National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc NBER Working Papers 2283

  • Ishiyama J (2012) The politics of appeasement? Politics and federal financial disbursements: the case of Ethiopia. Publ: J Fed 42(1):1–24

    Google Scholar 

  • Jenny H (1998) Fire from the ashes: a chronicle of the revolution in Tigray, Ethiopia, 1975–1991. Red Sea Press

  • Joanis M (2014) Shared accountability and partial decentralization in local public good provision. J Dev Econ 107(C):28–37

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johansson E (2003) Intergovernmental grants as a tactical instrument: empirical evidence from Swedish municipalities. J Public Econ 87(5–6):883–915

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Khemani S (2010) Political capture of decentralization: vote-buying through grants-financed local jurisdictions. The World Bank Policy Research Working Paper Series 5350

  • Khemani S (2007) Does delegation of fiscal policy to an independent agency make a difference? Evidence from intergovernmental transfers in India. J Dev Econ 82(2):464–484

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kimenyi MS (2006) Ethnicity, governance and the provision of public goods. J Afr Econ 15(1):62–99

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kramon E, Posner DN (2016) Ethnic favoritism in education in Kenya. Q J Polit Sci 11(1):1–58. https://doi.org/10.1561/100.00015005

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lockwood B (2005) Fiscal decentralization: a political economy perspective. University of Warwick, Department of Economics Economic Research Papers 269615

  • Lockwood B (2002) Distributive politics and the costs of centralization. Rev Econ Stud 69(2):313–337

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Luca G, Hodler R, Raschky P, Valsecchi M (2018) Ethnic favoritism: an axiom of politics? J Dev Econ 132(C):115–129

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maaser N, Stratmann T (2016) Distributional consequences of political representation. Eur Econ Rev 82(C):187–211

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mansuri G, Rao V (2013) Localizing development: Does participation work? World Bank Publications, The World Bank

    Google Scholar 

  • Marshall MG, Ted Robert G, Keith J (2018) Polity IV project: political regime characteristics and transitions, 1800–2017. http://www.systemicpeace.org/inscr/p4manualv2016.pdf. Center for Systemic Peace

  • Miguel E, Gugerty MK (2005) Ethnic diversity, social sanctions, and public goods in Kenya. J Public Econ 89(11–12):2325–2368

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mookherjee D (2015) Accountability of local and state governments in India: an overview of recent research. eSocialSciences Working Papers

  • Bardhan P, Mookherjee D (2000) Capture and governance at local and national levels. Am Econ Rev 90(2):135–139

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pande R (2003) Can mandated political representation increase policy influence for disadvantaged minorities? Theory and evidence from India. Am Econ Rev 93(4):1132–1151

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pereira PTC (1996) A politico-economic approach to intergovernmental lump-sum grants. Public Choice 88(1–2):185–201

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Porto A, Sanguinetti P (2001) Political determinants of intergovernmental grants: evidence From Argentina. Econ Polit 13(3):237–256

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pranab Bardhan, Mookherjee Dilip, ed. (2006b). decentralization and local governance in developing countries: a comparative perspective, vol 1. 1st edn. The MIT Press

  • Raleigh C, Linke A, Hegre H, Karlsen J (2010) Introducing ACLED: an armed conflict location and event dataset. J Peace Res 47(5):651–660

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reinikka R, Svensson J (2004) Local capture: evidence from a central government transfer program in Uganda. Q J Econ 119(2):679–705

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roth J, Sant’Anna PHC, Bilinski A, Poe J (2023) What’s trending in difference-in-differences? A synthesis of the recent econometrics literature. J Econometr 235(2):2218–2244

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schady NR (2000) The political economy of expenditures by the Peruvian Social Fund (FONCODES), 1991–1995. Am Polit Sci Rev 94(02):289–304

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Seabright P (1996) Accountability and decentralisation in government: An incomplete contracts model. Eur Econ Rev 40(1):61–89

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tommasi M, Weinschelbaum F (2007) Centralization vs. decentralization: a principal-agent analysis. J Public Econ Theory 9(2):369–389

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Treisman D (2002) Decentralization and the quality of government. Department of Political Science, UCLA Working Papers

  • Treisman D (1996) The politics of intergovernmental transfers in post-soviet Russia. Br J Polit Sci 26(03):299–335

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Treisman D (2007) What have we learned about the causes of corruption from ten years of cross-national empirical research? Annu Rev Polit Sci 10:211–244

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weingast BR, Shepsle KA, Johnsen C (1981) The political economy of benefits and costs: a neoclassical approach to distributive politics. J Polit Econ 89(4):642–664

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Worthington AC, Dollery BE (1998) The political determination of intergovernmental grants in Australia. Public Choice 94(3–4):299–315

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wright G (1974) The political economy of new deal spending: an econometric analysis. Rev Econ Stat 56(1):30–38

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Young J (1998) Regionalism and democracy in Ethiopia. Third World Q 19(2):191–204

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zewde B (2002) A history of modern Ethiopia: 1855–1991. Eastern African studies, 2nd edn. Ohio University Press

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Teferi Mergo.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix

Appendix A. Brief political background of modern Ethiopia

Ethiopia’s modern political history overlaps with the ‘Scramble for Africa’ by the European colonial powers in the late 19th century. Emperor Menelik the II (1889–1913) expanded his kingdom into what is today the southern half of the country, conquering the Oromo (the demographic majority of the country), the Somali and dozens of other ethnic groups currently making up Ethiopia (Zewde 2002). Menelik identified himself as an Amhara, a historically powerful group whose kings ruled over Abyssinia (Northern Ethiopia) for centuries, outmaneuvering the other key Abyssinian group, the Tegaru (Young 1998). With the exceptions of the Zagwe dynasty between about 900 and 1285, the Yeju Oromo effectively governing Abyssinia for about seventy years until 1853 and King Yohannes of Tigray wresting power from the Amhara kings for a little over a dozen years before Menelik assumed power, political life in Abyssinia and Ethiopia was dominated by the Amhara for centuries until the early 1990s (Bekele et al. 2016)).

Menelik II—who is largely credited with (and blamed for) giving Ethiopia its current shape (and multidimensional problems)—collaborated with the British, the French and the Italians to wrest power from the then Tegaru king, King Yohannes IV. This had been the source of a long-lasting resentment by the Tegaru for the next nearly 100 years, until the so-called Tigray People’s Liberation Front (TPLF)—assisted heavily by the Eritrean People’s Liberation Front (EPLF)—defeated the Ethiopian army in 1991 and installed itself—for all intents and purposes—as the government in Ethiopia, controlling key institutions including the defense and security establishments (Jenny 1998).

To extend their political longevity in Addis Ababa, the leaders of TPLF came up with mechanisms that would enable them to neutralize potentially significant rivalry from the Oromo and the Amhara, with both groups posing different but serious challenges that could prevent the TPLF from capturing the Ethiopian state for an extended period of time. The Amhara elites, in particular, who saw themselves as the creators and guardians of the Ethiopian state, would not tolerate playing second fiddle to the Tegaru when it comes to deciding the affairs of the country. The historically disenfranchised Oromo posed a different challenge in the form of the Oromo Liberation Front (OLF), which pushed for the rights to self-determination for the Oromo, including and up to secession of Oromia, the economic lifeline of the country. To outplay these forces, the TPLF established the so-called Oromo People’s Democratic Organization (OPDO) and the Amhara Nation Democratic Movement (ANDM), largely from the prisoners of war it captured from the now decommissioned Ethiopian army of Colonel Mengistu Hailemariam (Henze 2000). Similarly, the so-called Southern People’s Democratic Movement (SPDM) was created by the TPLF to purportedly serve as a political vehicle representing the various interests of the close to 50 ethnic groups in southern Ethiopia.

As described in the background section, the OPDO, the ANDM and the SPDM are thus essentially satellite organizations whose core leaderships’ access to power is determined by their subservience to the rules laid down by the dominant party, the TPLF. For all practical purposes, they served TPLF politicians and generals that controlled and commanded the heights of Ethiopia’s powerful institutions like the military, the security establishment, and key economic institutions.

In order to dominate the Ethiopian political landscape, the TPLF deployed a number of other tactics—some more subtle than others. Having engineered the re-organization of the country along ethno-linguistic lines in the early 1990s, which took effect through the constitution of 1995, the ruling party drove out its junior partner, the OLF, from the transitional government using its military might, putting in concentration camps tens of thousands of Oromos suspected of having nationalist/independent tendencies, sending an unmistakable signal to anyone that opposing the TPLF entails harsh consequences.Footnote 23 While continuing to crack down on any potentially serious political opposition, the TPLF had also been organizing sham parliamentary elections, ’winning’ nearly one hundred percent of the seats.Footnote 24 When the regime made some gesture towards opening the political space for the opposition in 2005, the experiment ended badly, with its armed personnel killing about two hundred people in the capital alone, while forcefully dispersing a crowd gathered to demonstrate against what was widely panned as flagrant vote-rigging by the regime.Footnote 25

Other indicators of the disenfranchisement of non-Tegarus in Ethiopia’s political life under the TPLF included the near-total decimation of independent media and civic organizations that are critical of the incumbent party. These facts have been well-documented by various credible foreign and international organizations, including the Human Rights Watch, PEN International, the US State Department, Amnesty International, etc. In particular, the TPLF pursued independent Oromo voices with such ferocity that a former Ethiopian Defense Minister from TPLF (who had fallen out with his former comrades) once described the situation as, "Ethiopia’s prisons speak the Oromo language." By some estimates, upwards of 90% of the close to 90,000 political prisoners in Ethiopia were believed to be of Oromo origin.Footnote 26

The imposed hegemony of the Tegaru ruling class on the rest of Ethiopia in the last twenty five years has, arguably, been the main cause of the recent mass rebellion in the country, particularly in the Oromia and Amhara regions. Since the beginning of what is now popularly known as the Oromo-Protests in 2014, thousands of Oromos and Amharas have been killed by armed personnel loyal to the Ethiopian government, almost pushing the country to a state of being ungovernable. According to the index compiled by the Fund for Peace and the American magazine Foreign Policy, the country has been one of the most fragile states, and losing its carefully crafted image of a developmental state that has managed to move on from a vicious cycle of civil conflict and abject poverty.

Before 1991, the Amhara ruling class pursued a policy of assimilation, inducing the occupied subjects to abandon their identities (language, culture, and religion) through an array of formal and informal institutions and mechanisms, with the goal of creating an Ethiopian identity with the Amhara language and culture as its core elements. Intermarriages—particularly between the Oromo and the Amhara—were encouraged at all socio-economic levels, and it appears that these policies had been partially successful, creating millions of multi-ethnic Ethiopians tracing their lineage to two or more national groups. In order to achieve this and other objectives required for the building of the Ethiopian empire, millions of Amharas were resettled throughout the country, particularly in Oromia, creating a situation where the Amhara are the demographic majority in some cities in Oromia, including the capital Addis Ababa, which is also the capital of Oromia. According to the Housing and Population Census of 2007, for instance, the Amhara constitute close to half of Addis Ababa’s residents, with the Oromo making up less than 20% of the population in the capital.

The dominance of Ethiopia’s political economy by the TPLF in the last twenty five years can be distinguished from that of the Amharas before 1991 in one key respect. In a break from the previous centralized polity, the Tigrayan elites pursued a strategy of ‘indirect rule’ to achieve their dominance. Using collaborators from each ethnic group as described above, they set up various extractive institutions whose key objectives appear to be the socio-economic advancement of Tigray. This is the focal point we concentrate the rest of the paper on, as we try to understand the mechanisms through which unequal political representation may translate into unequal access to public goods in the country.

Appendix B. Regional maps of Ethiopia

See Appendix Figs. 8 and 9.

Fig. 8
figure 8

Former provinces of Ethiopia before 1995 (source: https://www.mapsopensource.com/ethiopia-provinces-map.html)

Fig. 9
figure 9

Current ethno-linguistic regions after 1995 (Source: https://commons.wikimedia.org/wiki/File:Ethiopia_regions_english.png#/media/File:Ethiopia_regions_english.png)

Appendix C. Asset ownership rates comparison: Tigray vs. the rest

See Appendix Table 9.

Table 9 Comparison of asset ownership rates in Tigray and the control regions

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Mergo, T., Nimubona, AD. & Rus, H.A. Ethnically asymmetric political representation and the provision of public goods: theory and evidence from Ethiopia. Econ Gov 24, 519–547 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10101-023-00302-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10101-023-00302-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation