Skip to main content
Log in

The pure logic of discrimination

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Constitutional Political Economy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The paper expounds a simple non-cooperative game, which can model discrimination in market and non-market transactions. The model has two equilibriums where individuals do not discriminate and several where they do. One non-discriminatory equilibrium dominates in the sense of Pareto all discriminatory equilibriums. The second non-discriminatory equilibrium is dominated by all other equilibriums. While there is no discrimination in the first-best outcome, the introduction of discrimination can thus be Pareto-improving in some circumstances. For instance, in the model, a move from an equilibrium where they face discrimination to another equilibrium where they discriminate too can sometimes make the members of a group better off, without making anyone else worse off. Another implication of the model is that interactions between officials of the state and ordinary citizens generate a greater number of potential patterns of discrimination than interactions between ordinary citizens.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Varoufakis (2008) has used the hawk-dove game to model discrimination. The hawk-dove is a model of conflict between two players. When the two players belong to heterogenous populations, it has two evolutionary stable equilibriums, which consist for players of one population to use force (“play hawk”) and for players of the other population to submit to it (“play dove”) (Gintis, 2009; Selten, 1980). A structure of social interaction that is of an “us against them” variety can only have one form or another of coercion as a stable outcome.

  2. In one specification, Ertürk and Shrivastava’s model reduces to a single copy of the stag-hunt. It then has two (2) equilibriums: one in which the “minority” segregates and the other in which it integrates the “majority”.

References

  • Akerlof, G., & Kranton, R. (2010). Identity economics. Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. (1972a). Models of job discrimination. In A. Pascal (Ed.), Racial discrimination in economic life (pp. 83–102). Lexington.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. (1972b). Some mathematical models of race discrimination in the labor market. In A. Pascal (Ed.), Racial discrimination in economic life (pp. 187–203). Lexington.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. (1973). The theory of discrimination. In O. Ashenfelter & A. Rees (Eds.), Discrimination in Labor Markets (pp. 3–33). Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Basu, K. (2017). Discrimination as focal point: Markets and group identity. Forum for Social Economics, 46(2), 128–138.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. (1971). The economics of discrimination (2nd ed.). The University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Coate, S., & Loury, G. (1993). Will affirmative-action policies eliminate negative stereotypes? American Economic Review, 83(5), 1220–1240.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ertürk, K., & Shrivastava, S. (2023). Discrimination as social exclusion. Review of Social Economy. https://doi.org/10.1080/00346764.2023.2177329

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fang, H., & Moro, A. (2011). Theories of statistical discrimination and affirmative action: A survey. In J. Benhabib, A. Bisin, & M. Jackson (Eds.), Handbook of social economics (Vol. 1, pp. 133–200). North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fudenberg, D., & Tirole, J. (1991). Game theory. MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gintis, H. (2009). Game theory evolving (2nd ed.). Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Granovetter, M. (1985). Economic action and social structure: The problem of embeddedness. American Journal of Sociology, 91(3), 481–510.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guryan, J., & Charles, K. K. (2013). Taste-based or statistical discrimination: The economics of discrimination returns to its roots. Economic Journal, 123(572), F417–F432.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. (1937). Economics and knowledge. Economica, 4(13), 33–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knowles, J., Persico, N., & Todd, P. (2001). Racial bias in motor vehicle searches: Theory and evidence. Journal of Political Economy, 109(1), 203–229.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lang, K., & Kahn-Lang Spitzer, A. (2020). Race discrimination: An economic perspective. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 34(2), 68–89.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lang, K., & Lehmann, J. Y. (2012). Racial discrimination in the labour market: Theory and empirics. Journal of Economic Literature, 50(4), 959–1006.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loury, G. (2002). The anatomy of racial inequality. Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Merton, R. (1948). The self-fulfilling prophecy. The Antioch Review, 8(2), 193–210.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Phelps, E. (1972). The statistical theory of racism and sexism. American Economic Review, 62(4), 659–661.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rothstein, B. (2005). Social traps and the problem of trust. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Schelling, T. (1971). Dynamic models of segregation. Journal of Mathematical Sociology, 1(2), 143–186.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Selten, R. (1980). A note on evolutionary stable strategies in asymmetric animal conflicts. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 84, 93–101.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Small, M., & Pager, D. (2020). Sociological perspectives on racial discrimination. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 34(2), 49–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sowell, T. (2019). Discrimination and disparities. Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tajfel, H., Billig, M. G., Bundy, R. P., & Flament, C. (1971). Social categorization and intergroup behavior. European Journal of Social Psychology, 1(2), 149–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Varoufakis, Y. (2008). Capitalism according to evolutionary game theory: The impossibility of a sufficiently evolutionary model of historical change. Science & Society, 72(1), 63–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I wish to thank an anonymous referee for helpful comments and suggestions.

Funding

No funding was received to assist with the preparation of this manuscript.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

Louis Corriveau wrote and reviewed the manuscript.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Louis Corriveau.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The author has no relevant financial or non-financial interests to disclose.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Corriveau, L. The pure logic of discrimination. Const Polit Econ (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-023-09419-8

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-023-09419-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation