Skip to main content
Log in

Corporate Social Responsibility, Environmental Emissions and Time-Consistent Taxation

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We formally model a Cournot duopoly market in which a corporate socially responsible (CSR) firm interacts with a profit-maximizing firm and where the market is regulated with an emission tax. We consider three different kinds of CSR firm behaviors: (i) consumer-friendly; (ii) environmentally-friendly; and (iii) consumer-environmentally friendly. Unlike most theoretical works within this literature, which typically use specific functional forms, we use general structures for the inverse demand function, the cost function, and for emission levels and damage functions. In terms of modeling strategy, we use two game-theoretic approaches: (i) a simultaneous game and (ii) a sequential three-stage ex-post game, in which decisions are time consistent. We found that the optimal emissions taxation rule is modified when considering different CSR motivations. We show that depending upon the CSR motivation and the price elasticity of demand in some cases we can obtain optimal emission tax rates higher, lower, or equal to marginal external emission. Finally, we also found that firms adopting consumer-friendly CSR behavior are more effective in improving the environment compared to environmentally friendly firms.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The KPMG Survey of Sustainability Reporting 2020: https://home.kpmg/xx/en/home/insights/2020/11/the-time-has-come-survey-of-sustainability-reporting.html.

  2. For details see: “Global sustainable investing assets surged to $30 trillion in 2018”. Greenbiz. Retrieved july 2023. https://www.greenbiz.com/article/global-sustainable-investing-assets-surged-30-trillion-2018.

  3. https://www.carthrottle.com/post/volvo-has-finally-confirmed-the-end-of-its-diesel-engines.

  4. https://www.wemeanbusinesscoalition.org/blog/bmw-joins-growing-list-of-automakers-committed-to-bold-climate-action/.

  5. SeePetrakis and Xepapadeas (2003) and Moner-Colonques and Rubio (2016).

  6. In fact, according to Petrakis and Xepapadeas (2001) rules are not necessarily better than discretion for controlling emissions.

  7. For details, see, inter alia: Besley and Ghatak (2007), Chang et al. (2014), Kirchhoff (2000), Lee and Park (2019), Matsumura and Ogawa (2014), and Yanase (2012). For review articles about CSR see as well: McWilliams et al. (2006), Carroll and Shabana (2010), and Kitzmueller and Shimshack (2012).

  8. (For further details see the Becker–Posner Blog February 10, 2008: “On Corporate Altruism–Becker”.

  9. Since we define social welfare as. \(SW\triangleq CS+(f(Q)q_{0}-c_{0}-d_{0}t)+(f(Q)q_{1}-c_{1}-d_{1}t)+(d_{0}t +d_{1}t)-D(d_0(q_0,w_0),d_1(q_1,w_1))\) we can notice that taxes are merely income transfers from the firms to the government, and therefore, they are canceled out.

  10. Note that by assumptions 3 and 4 we have that \(-\gamma \frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{0}}\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}>0\).

  11. In fact, as also noted by Petrakis and Xepapadeas (2003), the two firms in the duopoly can strategically choose their abatement efforts in order to influence the emission tax the government will eventually levy.

  12. For further details see the seminal work by Bulow et al. (1985) or a very clear exposition by Loomis (1997).

  13. We thank a referee for suggesting this further analysis.

References

  • Bárcena-Ruiz JC, Sagasta A (2022) International trade and environmental corporate social responsibility. Energy Econ 115:106104

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barman E (2018) Doing well by doing good: a comparative analysis of ESG standards for responsible investment, sustainability, stakeholder governance, and corporate social responsibility. Adv Strateg Manag 38:289–311

    Google Scholar 

  • Barnett AH (1980) The Pigouvian tax rule under monopoly. Am Econ Rev 70(5):1037–1041

    Google Scholar 

  • Baron DP (2007) Corporate social responsibility and social entrepreneurship. J Econ Manag Strategy 16(4):539–545

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baron DP (2008) Managerial contracting and corporate social responsibility. J Public Econ 92(1–2):268–288

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumol WJ (1972) On taxation and the control of externalities. Am Econ Rev 62(3):307–322

    Google Scholar 

  • Bénabou R, Tirole J (2010) Individual and corporate social responsibility. Econ 77(305):1–19

  • Besley T, Ghatak M (2007) Retailing public goods: the economics of corporate social responsibility. J Public Econ 91(9):1645–1663

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brand B, Grothe M (2015) Social responsibility in a bilateral monopoly. J Econ 115:275–289

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bulow JI, Geanakoplos JD, Klemperer PD (1985) Multimarket oligopoly: strategic substitutes and complements. J Polit Econ 93(3):488–511

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carroll AB, Shabana KM (2010) The business case for corporate social responsibility: a review of concepts, research and practice. Int J Manag Rev 12(1):85–105

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang YM, Chen HY, Wang LF, Wu SJ (2014) Corporate social responsibility and international competition: a welfare analysis. Rev Int Econ 22(3):625–638

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheng B, Ioannou I, Serafeim G (2014) Corporate social responsibility and access to finance. Strateg Manag J 35(1):1–23

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elkington J (2013) Enter the triple bottom line. In: The triple bottom line. Routledge, pp 1–16

  • Fanti L, Buccella D (2017) Corporate social responsibility, profits and welfare with managerial firms. Int Rev Econ 64:341–356

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fiksel J, Lal R (2018) Transforming waste into resources for the Indian economy. Environ Dev 26:123–128

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flammer C (2013) Corporate social responsibility and shareholder reaction: the environmental awareness of investors. Acad Manag J 56(3):758–781

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flammer C (2015) Does corporate social responsibility lead to superior financial performance? A regression discontinuity approach. Manag Sci 61(11):2549–2568

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flammer C (2018) Competing for government procurement contracts: the role of corporate social responsibility. Strateg Manag J 39(5):1299–1324

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flammer C, Luo J (2017) Corporate social responsibility as an employee governance tool: evidence from a quasi-experiment. Strateg Manag J 38(2):163–183

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friede G, Busch T, Bassen A (2015) ESG and financial performance: aggregated evidence from more than 2000 empirical studies. J Sustain Finance Invest 5(4):210–233

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fukuda K, Ouchida Y (2020) Corporate social responsibility (CSR) and the environment: Does CSR increase emissions? Energy Econ 92:104933

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garcia A, Leal M, Lee SH (2018) Time-inconsistent environmental policies with a consumer-friendly firm: tradable permits versus emission tax. Int Rev Econ Finance 58:523–537

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goering GE (2014) The profit-maximizing case for corporate social responsibility in a bilateral monopoly. Manag Decis Econ 35(7):493–499

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirose K, Lee SH, Matsumura T (2020) Noncooperative and cooperative environmental corporate social responsibility. J Inst Theor Econ 176(3):549–571

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kirchhoff S (2000) Green business and blue angels. Environ Resour Econ 15(4):403–420

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kitzmueller M, Shimshack J (2012) Economic perspectives on corporate social responsibility. J Econ Lit 50(1):51–84

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kopel M, Brand B (2012) Socially responsible firms and endogenous choice of strategic incentives. Econ Model 29(3):982–989

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lambertini L, Tampieri A (2015) Incentives, performance and desirability of socially responsible firms in a Cournot oligopoly. Econ Model 50:40–48

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leal M, Garcia A, Lee SH (2018) The timing of environmental tax policy with a consumer-friendly firm. Hitotsubashi J Econ 59:25–43

    Google Scholar 

  • Leal M, Garcia A, Lee SH (2019) Excess burden of taxation and environmental policy mix with a consumer-friendly firm. Jpn Econ Rev 70:517–536

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee SH, Park CH (2019) Eco-firms and the sequential adoption of environmental corporate social responsibility in the managerial delegation. BE J Theor Econ 19(1):20170043

    Google Scholar 

  • Liu Q, Wang LF, Chen CL (2018) CSR in an oligopoly with foreign competition: policy and welfare implications. Econ Model 72:1–7

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loomis DG (1997) Strategic substitutes and strategic complements with interdependent demands. Rev Ind Organ 12:781–791

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsumura T, Ogawa A (2014) Corporate social responsibility or payoff asymmetry? A study of an endogenous timing game. South Econ J 81(2):457–473

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McWilliams A, Siegel DS, Wright PM (2006) Corporate social responsibility: strategic implications. J Manag Stud 43(1):1–18

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moner-Colonques R, Rubio SJ (2016) The strategic use of innovation to influence environmental policy: taxes versus standards. BE J Econ Anal Policy 16(2):973–1000

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mohr LA, Webb DJ, Harris KE (2001) Do consumers expect companies to be socially responsible? The impact of corporate social responsibility on buying behavior. J Consum Aff 35(1):45–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Orlitzky M, Schmidt FL, Rynes SL (2003) Corporate social and financial performance: a meta-analysis. Organ Stud 24(3):403–441

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Petrakis E, Xepapadeas A (2003) Location decisions of a polluting firm and the time consistency of environmental policy. Resour Energy Econ 25(2):197–214

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Petrakis E, Xepapadeas A (2001) To commit or not to commit: Environmental policy in imperfectly competitive markets. Typescript Dept of Eco University of Crete

  • Pigou AC (1920) The economics of welfare. Macmillan, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Porter ME, Kramer MR (2006) The link between competitive advantage and corporate social responsibility. Harv Bus Rev 84(12):78–92

    Google Scholar 

  • Stranlund JK, Chavez CA, Villena MG (2009) The optimal pricing of pollution when enforcement is costly. J Environ Econ Manag 58(2):183–191

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • United Nations Sustainable Developments Goals (2023) 17 goals for people, for planet. Retrieved 21 July 2023. https://www.un.org/sustainabledevelopment/development-agenda/

  • United Nations Environment Programme—Finance Initiative (2004) Who cares wins: the global compact connecting financial markets to a changing world. Retrieved 21 July 2023

  • Wang LF, Wang YC, Zhao L (2012) Tariff policy and welfare in an international duopoly with consumer-friendly initiative. Bull Econ Res 64(1):56–64

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Xu L, Lee SH (2018) Environmental policies with excess burden of taxation in free-entry mixed markets. Int Rev Econ Finance 58:1–13

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Xu L, Lee SH (2022) Non-cooperative and cooperative environmental corporate social responsibility with emission taxes. Manag Decis Econ 43(7):2849–2862

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yanase A (2012) Trade and global pollution in dynamic oligopoly with corporate environmentalism. Rev Int Econ 20(5):924–943

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to thank Professor Mireille Chiroleu-Assouline Co-Editor of Environmental and Resource Economics and two anonymous referees for helpful suggestions that substantially improved this article. In addition, Professors Carlos Chavez, Marcelo Villena and Dany Jaimovich, provided valuable input on an earlier draft of this paper. As usual, any errors remain the responsibility of the authors.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Mauricio G. Villena.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendices

Alternative CSR-Firm’s Objective Functions Used in the Literature

Authors

Title

Year

CSR-firm’s objective function

CSR firms as consumer-friendly firms

Seung-Leul Kim, Sang-Ho Lee. and Tosliihiro Matsumura

Corporate social responsibility and privatization policy in a mixed oligopoly

2019

\({U}_{{{i}}} = \pi _{{{i}}} + \alpha _{i}CS\). where \(\alpha _{i}\) (\(0< \alpha _{i} < 1\)) represents the CSR level, which is exogenously given. That is, CSR implies the private firm is interested in consumers’ surplus in addition to its profit. CS stands for consumer surplus.

Arturo Garcia, Mariel Leal and Sang-Ho Lee

Time-inconsistent environmental policies with a consumer-friendly firm: Tradable permits versus emission tax

2018

\(V_{0} = \pi _{0} + {\theta }CS\). where the parameter \(\theta \in [0,1]\) measures the degree of concern on consumer surplus that the consumer-friendly firm has. which is exogenously given. CS stands for consumer surplus.

Lili Xn and Sang-Ho Lee

Corporate Social Responsibility and Environmental Taxation with Endogenous Entry

2018

\(G=\pi _{0}+\alpha CS\). where \(\alpha \in [0,1]\), CS is consumer surplus. They assume that CSR. initiative includes both profitability and consumer surplus, as a proxy of its own concern on consumers, and thus the objective of the CSR-firm is a combination of consumers surplus and its own profit.

Luciano Fanti and Domenico Buccella

Corporate social responsibility, profits and welfare with managerial firms

2017

\(W_{i} = \pi _{i} + kCS\). where \(k \in [0,1]\) denotes the weight that CSR firms assign to consumer surplus. CS stands for consumer surplus.

Luca Lambertini and Alessandro Tampieri

Incentives, performance and desirability of socially responsible firms in a Cournot oligopoly

2015

\(O_{csr}=\pi _{csr}- gq_{csr} + z\frac{Q^{2}}{2}\), where \(O_{csr}\) represents the objective function of a firm adopting a CSR statute, gqcsr represents environmental damage and \(z \in [0, 1]\) denotes the weight that the firm assigns to consumer surplus.

Tosliihiro Matsumura and Akira Ogawa

Corporate Social Responsibility or Payoff Asymmetry? A Study of an Endogenous Timing Game

2014

\(V_{i} = \theta _{i}SW + (1 - \theta _{i})\pi _{i}\), where \(\theta _{i} \in [0,1)\). SW is the total social surplus (sum of the firms’ profits and consumer surplus), and 7rt is firm i’s profit.

Gregory E. Goering

The Profit-Maximizing Case for Corporate Social Responsibility in a Bilateral Monopoly

2014

\(\lambda _{r} = \pi _{r} + {\gamma }CS\) where \(\pi _{r}\) represents profits plus a given fraction (\(\gamma >0\)) of the consumer surplus (CS) of its customers’ (stakeholders’).

Bjorn Brand and Michael Grothe

Social responsibility in a bilateral monopoly

2014

\(v_{i} = \pi _{i} + \theta _{i}CS\), where \(\theta _{i}\) indicates the weight put on consumer surplus. CS stands for consumer surplus. For \(\theta _{i} = 0\) the firm operates like a profit maximizer while for \(\theta _{i} = 1\) the whole consumer surplus is considered in the firm’s objective function.

Michael Kopel and Bjorn Brand

Socially responsible firms and endogenous choice of strategic incentives

2012

\(U_{SR} = \pi _{SR} + {\theta }CS + {\gamma }SR (CS - \pi _{SR})\). the compensation contract gives incentives to contribute to socially responsible (SR) firm’s objective including the non-profit motives, but corrects for differences between the two components consumer surplus CS and profit \(\pi _{SR}\). For \({\gamma }_{SR} = 0\) the SR. manager’s goal coincides with the firm’s objective.

CSR firms as environment-friendly firms

Juan Carlos Barcena-Ruiz, Amagoia Sagasta

International trade and environmental corporate social responsibility

2022

\(V_{i} = \pi _{i} - {\alpha }ED_{i},i \ne j; \hbox {i,j} = 1,2\). where aEDt can be interpreted as measuring the cost of factoring environmental considerations into all business activities. Parameter \(\alpha\). which is assumed equal for both firms, denotes the weight that firm i places on environmental damage in addition to its profits and thus represents the degree of ECSR. Hence, \(\alpha = 0\) means that the owner of firm i is only concerned about its profit and the higher parameter \(\alpha\) is, the greater the concern of firm i for environmental damage is. The weight attached to environmental damage by firm i, \(\alpha\). is exogenous, with \(\alpha \in [0,1/2]\).

Lili Xu. Yuyan Chen and Sang-Ho Lee

Emission tax and strategic’ environmental corporate social responsibility in a Cournot Bertrand comparison

2022

\(V_{\i } = \pi _{i} - \beta _{i}ED\). where \(\beta _{i} \in [0,1]\) represents the degree of ECSR (environmental corporate social responsibility) and ED represents environmental damage. Note that \(\beta _{i} = 0\) indicates that firm i is a private firm pursuing absolute profits.

Katsufumi Fukuda and Yasunori Ouchidab

Corporate social responsibility (CSR) and the environment: Does CSR increase emissions?

2022

\(V = \pi + \theta \langle CS - D(E)\rangle\) where the exogenous parameter \(\theta \in [0,1]\) presents the degree of CSR. A higher value of \(\theta\) denotes a higher degree of CSR. \(\theta \langle CS - D(E)\rangle\) is called social concern. When \(\theta =0\), then the firm maximizes only its own profit. Conversely, when \(\theta = 1\), then the monopolist behaves as the most socially responsible firm. CS stands for consumer surplus and D(E) for environmental damage.

Proof Proposition 1

Proof

Solving for (6) we have: \(\frac{\partial v_{0}(q_{0},w_{0})}{\partial q_{0}}=f(Q^{*})+q_{0}^{*}\frac{\partial f(Q^{*})}{\partial q_{0}}-\frac{\partial c_{0}^{*}}{\partial q_{0}}-t\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial q_{0}}+\theta \left( f(Q^{*})\frac{\partial Q^{*}}{\partial q_{0}}-f(Q^{*})\frac{\partial Q^{*}}{\partial q_{0}}-\frac{\partial f(Q^{*})}{\partial q_{0}}Q^{*}\right) -\gamma \frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{0}}\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial q_{0}}=0\)

\(\Longrightarrow f(Q^{*})+q_{0}^{*}\frac{\partial f(Q^{*})}{\partial q_{0}}-\frac{\partial c_{0}^{*}}{\partial q_{0}}-t\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial q_{0}}+\theta f(Q^{*})\frac{\partial Q^{*}}{\partial q_{0}}-\theta f(Q^{*})\frac{\partial Q^{*}}{\partial q_{0}}-\theta \frac{\partial f(Q^{*})}{\partial q_{0}}Q^{*}-\gamma \frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{0}}\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial q_{0}}=0\).

Cancelling out the term \(\theta f(Q^{*})\frac{\partial Q^{*}}{\partial q_{0}}\), we get (i).

From (6) we also obtain:

\(\frac{\partial v_{0}(q_{0},w_{0})}{\partial w_{0}}=-\frac{\partial c_{0}^{*}}{\partial w_{0}}-t\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial w_{0}}+\theta \left( f(Q^{*})\frac{\partial Q^{*}}{\partial w_{0}}-f(Q^{*})\frac{\partial Q^{*}}{\partial w_{0}}-\frac{\partial f(Q^{*})}{\partial w_{0}}Q^{*}\right) -\gamma \frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{0}}\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{ \partial w_{0}}=0\)

\(\Longrightarrow -\frac{\partial c_{0}^{*}}{\partial w_{0}}-t\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial w_{0}}+\theta f(Q^{*})\frac{\partial Q^{*}}{\partial w_{0}}-\theta f(Q^{*})\frac{\partial Q^{*}}{\partial w_{0}}-\theta \frac{\partial f(Q^{*})}{\partial w_{0}}Q^{*}-\gamma \frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{0}}\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial w_{0}}=0\).

Cancelling out the term \(\theta f(Q^{*})\frac{\partial Q^{*}}{\partial w_{0}}\), we get: \(-\frac{\partial c_{0}^{*}}{\partial w_{0}}-t\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial w_{0}}-\theta \frac{\partial f(Q^{*})}{\partial w_{0}}Q^{*}-\gamma \frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{0}}\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial w_{0}}=0\). Since \(\frac{\partial f(Q^{*})}{\partial w_{0}}=0\), we get (ii).

Solving for (5) we have:

\(\frac{\partial \pi _{1}(q_{1},w_{1})}{\partial q_{1}}=f(Q^{*})+q_{1}^{*}\frac{\partial f(Q^{*})}{\partial q_{1}}-\frac{\partial c_{1}^{*}}{\partial q_{1}}-t\frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial q_{1}}=0\). Hence (iii).

From (5) we also obtain: \(\frac{\partial \pi _{1}(q_{1},w_{1})}{\partial w_{1}}=-\frac{\partial c_{1}^{*}}{\partial w_{1}}-t\frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial w_{1}}=0\). Thus (iv). \(\square\)

Proof Proposition 2

Proof

It can be noted that:\(\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}=\frac{ \partial d_{0}}{\partial q_{0}}\frac{dq_{0}^{*}}{dt}+\frac{\partial d_{0} }{\partial w_{0}}\frac{dw_{0}^{*}}{dt}\) and \(\frac{\partial d_{1}^{*} }{\partial t}=\frac{\partial d_{1}}{\partial q_{1}}\frac{dq_{1}^{*}}{dt}+ \frac{\partial d_{1}}{\partial w_{1}}\frac{dw_{1}^{*}}{dt}\), which are the equilibrium emissions levels: \(d_{\acute{\imath }}(q^{*}(t),w^{*}(t))\), (for \(i=0,1)\), derived by totally differentiating emissions levels with respect to t.

Replacing these expressions into (8), we obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} f(Q^{*})\frac{\partial Q^{*}}{\partial t}-\left[ \frac{ \partial c_{0}^{*}}{\partial q_{0}}\frac{dq_{0}^{*}}{dt}+\frac{ \partial c_{0}^{*}}{\partial w_{0}}\frac{dw_{0}^{*}}{dt}\right] - \left[ \frac{\partial c_{1}^{*}}{\partial q_{1}}\frac{dq_{1}^{*}}{dt} +\frac{\partial c_{1}^{*}}{\partial w_{1}}\frac{dw_{1}^{*}}{dt} \right] =\frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{0}}\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{ \partial t}+\frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{1}}\frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{ \partial t}. \end{aligned}$$

Distributing the negative sign in the LHS:

$$\begin{aligned} f(Q^{*})\frac{ \partial Q^{*}}{\partial t}-\frac{\partial c_{0}^{*}}{\partial q_{0}} \frac{dq_{0}^{*}}{dt}-\frac{\partial c_{0}^{*}}{\partial w_{0}}\frac{ dw_{0}^{*}}{dt}-\frac{\partial c_{1}^{*}}{\partial q_{1}}\frac{ dq_{1}^{*}}{dt}-\frac{\partial c_{1}^{*}}{\partial w_{1}}\frac{ dw_{1}^{*}}{dt}=\frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{0}}\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}+\frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{1}}\frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}. \end{aligned}$$

Combining this equation with the ones highlighted in Proposition 1, we obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{0}}\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}+\frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{1}}\frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}= & {} f(Q^{*})\frac{\partial Q^{*}}{\partial t}-\left( f(Q)+q_{0}\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{0}}-t\frac{\partial d_{0}}{\partial q_{0}}-\theta Q\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{0}}-\gamma \frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{0}}\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial q_{0}}\right) \frac{dq_{0}^{*}}{dt}\\{} & {} +\left( t\frac{\partial d_{0}}{\partial w_{0}}+\gamma \frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{0}}\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial w_{0}}\right) \frac{dw_{0}^{*}}{dt}-\left( f(Q)+q_{1}\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{1}}-t\frac{\partial d_{1}}{\partial q_{1}}\right) \frac{dq_{1}^{*}}{dt}-\left( -t\frac{\partial d_{1}}{\partial w_{1}}\right) \frac{dw_{1}^{*}}{dt}. \end{aligned}$$

Collecting terms in the LHS we get:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{0}}\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}+\frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{1}}\frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}= & {} \frac{\partial d_{0}}{\partial q_{0}}\frac{dq_{0}^{*}}{dt}\left( t+\gamma \frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{0}}\right) +\frac{\partial d_{0}}{\partial w_{0}}\frac{dw_{0}^{*}}{dt}\left( t+\gamma \frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{0}}\right) + t\left( \frac{\partial d_{1}}{\partial q_{1}}\frac{dq_{1}^{*}}{dt}+\frac{\partial d_{1}}{\partial w_{1}}\frac{dw_{1}^{*}}{dt}\right) \\{} & {} +\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{0}}\frac{dq_{0}^{*}}{dt}\left( -q_{0}+\theta Q\right) +f(Q^{*})\left( \frac{\partial Q^{*}}{\partial t}-\frac{dq_{0}^{*}}{dt}-\frac{dq_{1}^{*}}{dt}\right) -q_{1}\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{1}}\frac{dq_{1}^{*} }{dt}. \end{aligned}$$

Given that \(Q=q_{0}+q_{1}\), differentiating with respect to t we obtain:

\(\frac{\partial Q^{*}}{\partial t}=\frac{dq_{0}^{*}}{dt}+\frac{dq_{1}^{*}}{dt}\) and so \(\frac{\partial Q^{*}}{\partial t}-\frac{dq_{0}^{*}}{dt}-\frac{dq_{1}^{*}}{dt}=0\).

Collecting terms in the LHS we obtain: \(\frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{0}} \frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}+\frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{1}} \frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}=\left( t+\gamma \frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{0}}\right) \left( \frac{\partial d_{0} }{\partial q_{0}}\frac{dq_{0}^{*}}{dt}+\frac{\partial d_{0}}{\partial w_{0}}\frac{dw_{0}^{*}}{dt}\right) +t\left( \frac{\partial d_{1}}{ \partial q_{1}}\frac{dq_{1}^{*}}{dt}+\frac{\partial d_{1}}{\partial w_{1} }\frac{dw_{1}^{*}}{dt}\right) +\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{0}}\frac{ dq_{0}^{*}}{dt}\left( -q_{0}+\theta Q\right) -q_{1}\frac{\partial f(Q)}{ \partial q_{1}}\frac{dq_{1}^{*}}{dt}\).

Replacing \(\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}\)and \(\frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}\) and rearranging terms, we get:

$$\begin{aligned} \left( t+\gamma \frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{0}}\right) \frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}+t\frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}-\frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{0}} \frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}-\frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{1}}\frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}=\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{0}}\frac{dq_{0}^{*}}{dt}\left( q_{0}-\theta Q\right) +q_{1}\frac{dq_{1}^{*}}{dt}\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{1}}. \end{aligned}$$

Finally, collecting terms in the LHS we get (9). \(\square\)

Proof Corollary 1

Proof

Rearranging (9) we obtain: \(t^{*}\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}-\left( 1-\gamma \right) \frac{\partial D^{*}}{ \partial d_{0}}\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}+t^{*}\frac{ \partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}-\frac{\partial D^{*}}{\partial d_{1}} \frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}=q_{0}^{*}\frac{dq_{0}^{*}}{ dt}\frac{\partial f(Q^{*})}{\partial q_{0}}-\theta Q^{*}\frac{ dq_{0}^{*}}{dt}\frac{\partial f(Q^{*})}{\partial q_{0}}+q_{1}^{*} \frac{dq_{1}^{*}}{dt}\frac{\partial f(Q^{*})}{\partial q_{1}}\), which we differentiate by \(\gamma\) and get:\(\frac{dt^{*}}{d\gamma }=- \frac{\frac{\partial D^{*}}{\partial d_{0}}\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{ \partial t}}{\left( \frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}+\frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}\right) }\), which by assumptions 3, we know that \(\frac{\partial D^{*}}{\partial d_{0}}>0\). Regardless of the sign of \(\frac{\partial d_{i}^{*}}{\partial t}\), we get that: \(\frac{dt^{*}}{d\gamma }<0\).

Now differentiating this expression by \(\theta\) and rearranging terms we obtain:\(\frac{dt^{*}}{d\theta }=- \frac{Q^{*}\frac{\partial q_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}\frac{\partial f(Q^{*})}{ \partial q_{0}}}{\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}+\frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}}\), differentiating Proposition 1, panel i with respect to t allow us conclude that \(sign\left( \frac{\partial q_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}\right) =sign\left( \frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}\right)\), which implies that \(\frac{\frac{\partial q_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}}{\frac{\partial d_0^*}{\partial t}+\frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}}>0\), and then: \(\frac{dt^{*}}{d\theta }>0\). \(\square\)

Proof Corollary 2

Proof

Case (i): (\(\theta =0\) and \(\gamma =0)\)).

From (9) we obtain:\(\left( t^{*}-\frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{0}}\right) \left( \frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}\right) +\left( t^{*}-\frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{1}}\right) \left( \frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}\right) =\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{0}}\frac{dq_{0}^{*}}{dt}\left( q_{0}\right) +q_{1}\frac{dq_{1}^{*}}{dt}\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{1}}\).

After distributing terms in the LHS we get: \(t^{*}\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}-\frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{0}}\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}+t^{*}\frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}-\frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{1}}\frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}=q_{0}\frac{dq_{0}^{*}}{dt}\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{0}}+q_{1}\frac{dq_{1}^{*}}{dt}\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{1}}\Longrightarrow t^{*}\left( \frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}+\frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}\right) = \frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{1}}\frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}+\frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{0}}\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}+q_{0}\frac{dq_{0}^{*}}{dt}\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{0}}+q_{1}\frac{dq_{1}^{*}}{dt}\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{1}}\).

Finally, clearing for \(t^{*}\), which we now denote by \(t_{pm}^{*}\) we get: \(t_{pm}^{*}=\frac{\frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{1}}\frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}+\frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{0}}\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}+q_{0}\frac{dq_{0}^{*}}{dt}\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{0}}+q_{1}\frac{dq_{1}^{*}}{dt}\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{1}}}{\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}+\frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}}\).

Case (ii): (\(\theta >0\) and \(\gamma =0\)).

From (9) we get:\(\left( t^{*}-\frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{0}}\right) \left( \frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}\right) +\left( t^{*}-\frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{1}}\right) \left( \frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}\right) =\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{0}}\frac{dq_{0}^{*}}{dt}\left( q_{0}-\theta Q\right) +q_{1}\frac{dq_{1}^{*}}{dt}\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{1}}\).

After distributing terms in the LHS we obtain: \(t^{*}\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}-\frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{0}}\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}+t^{*}\frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}-\frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{1}}\frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}=\left( q_{0}-\theta Q\right) \frac{dq_{0}^{*}}{dt}\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{0}}+q_{1}\frac{dq_{1}^{*}}{dt}\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{1}}\Longrightarrow t^{*}\left( \frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}+\frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}\right) =\frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{1}}\frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}+\frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{0}}\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}+\left( q_{0}-\theta Q\right) \frac{dq_{0}^{*}}{dt}\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{0}}+q_{1}\frac{dq_{1}^{*}}{dt}\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{1}}\).

Finally, clearing for \(t^{*}\), which we now denote by \(t_{cf}^{*}\) we get: \(t_{cf}^{*}=\frac{\frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{1}}\frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}+\frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{0}}\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}+\left( q_{0}-\theta Q\right) \frac{dq_{0}^{*}}{dt}\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{0}}+q_{1}\frac{dq_{1}^{*}}{dt}\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{1}}}{\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}+\frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}}\).

Case (iii): (\(\theta =0\) and \(\gamma >0\)).

From (9) we get: \(\left( t^{*}-\frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{0}}\left( 1-\gamma \right) \right) \left( \frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}\right) +\left( t^{*}-\frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{1}}\right) \left( \frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}\right) =q_{0}\frac{dq_{0}^{*}}{dt}\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{0}}+q_{1}\frac{dq_{1}^{*}}{dt}\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{1}}\).

After distributing terms in the LHS we obtain: \(t^{*}\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}-\left( 1-\gamma \right) \frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{0}}\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}+t^{*}\frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}-\frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{1}}\frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}=q_{0}\frac{dq_{0}^{*}}{dt}\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{0}}+q_{1}\frac{dq_{1}^{*}}{dt}\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{1}}\Longrightarrow t^{*}\left( \frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}+\frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}\right) =\left( 1-\gamma \right) \frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{0}}\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}+\frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{1}}\frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}+q_{0}\frac{dq_{0}^{*}}{dt}\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{0}}+q_{1}\frac{dq_{1}^{*}}{dt}\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{1}}\).

Finally, clearing for \(t^{*}\), which we now denote by \(t_{ef}^{*}\) we get we get:

$$\begin{aligned} t_{ef}^{*}=\frac{\left( 1-\gamma \right) \frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{0}}\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}+\frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{1}}\frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}+q_{0}\frac{dq_{0}^{*}}{dt}\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{0}}+q_{1}\frac{dq_{1}^{*}}{dt}\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{1}}.}{\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}+\frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}}. \end{aligned}$$

Case (iv): (\(\theta >0\) and \(\gamma >0)\).

From (9) we get:\(\left( t^{*}-\frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{0}}\left( 1-\gamma \right) \right) \left( \frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}\right) +\left( t^{*}-\frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{1}}\right) \left( \frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}\right) =\left( q_{0}-\theta Q\right) \frac{dq_{0}^{*}}{dt}\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{0}}+q_{1}\frac{dq_{1}^{*}}{dt}\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{1}}\).

After distributing terms in the LHS we obtain: \(t^{*}\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}-\left( 1-\gamma \right) \frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{0}}\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}+t^{*}\frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}-\frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{1}}\frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}=\left( q_{0}-\theta Q\right) \frac{dq_{0}^{*}}{dt}\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{0}}+q_{1}\frac{dq_{1}^{*}}{dt}\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{1}}\Longrightarrow t^{*}\left( \frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}+\frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}\right) =\left( 1-\gamma \right) \frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{0}}\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}+ \frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{1}}\frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}+\left( q_{0}-\theta Q\right) \frac{dq_{0}^{*}}{dt}\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{0}}+q_{1}\frac{dq_{1}^{*}}{dt}\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{1}}\).

Finally, clearing for \(t^{*}\), which we now denote by \(t_{cef}^{*}\) we get we get:

$$\begin{aligned} t_{cef}^{*}=\frac{\left( 1-\gamma \right) \frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{0}}\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}+\frac{\partial D}{\partial d_{1}}\frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}+\left( q_{0}-\theta Q\right) \frac{dq_{0}^{*}}{dt}\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{0}}+q_{1}\frac{dq_{1}^{*}}{dt}\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_{1}}}{\frac{\partial d_{0}^{*}}{\partial t}+\frac{\partial d_{1}^{*}}{\partial t}}. \end{aligned}$$

\(\square\)

Proof Proposition 4

Proof

Using the fact that from stage 2 we also get \(c_0^{(2)}(w_0,w_1)\), \(c_1^{(2)}(w_0,w_1)\), \(d_0^{(2)}(w_0,w_1)\), \(d_1^{(2)}(w_0,w_1)\) and \(D^{(2)}(w_0,w_1)\) in Eqs. (17) and (18) we get:

$$\begin{aligned}{} & {} f(Q)= \frac{\frac{\partial c_1}{\partial w_1}+t\frac{\partial d_1}{\partial w_1}+d_1\frac{\partial t}{\partial w_1}-q_1\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial w_1}}{\frac{\partial q_1}{\partial w_1}}\\{} & {} f\left( Q\right) \frac{\partial q_0}{\partial w_0}= \frac{\frac{\partial c_0}{\partial w_0}+t\frac{\partial d_0}{\partial w_0}+d_0\frac{\partial t}{\partial w_0}+\theta Q\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial w_0}+\gamma \frac{\partial D}{\partial w_0}-q_0\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial w_0}}{\frac{\partial q_0}{\partial w_0}} \end{aligned}$$

Equating the equations above we get Proposition 4\(\square\)

Proof Corollary 3

Proof

Solving Proposition 4 for t, we have that:

$$\begin{aligned} t^*=\frac{\frac{\partial q_1}{\partial w_1}\left( \frac{\partial c_0}{\partial w_0}+d_0\frac{\partial t}{\partial w_0}+\theta Q\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial w_0}+\gamma \frac{\partial D}{\partial w_0}-q_0\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial w_0}\right) -\frac{\partial q_0}{\partial w_0}\left( \frac{\partial c_1}{\partial w_1}+d_1\frac{\partial t}{\partial w_1}-q_1\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial w_1}\right) }{\frac{\partial q_0}{\partial w_0}\frac{\partial d_1}{\partial w_1}-\frac{\partial q_1}{\partial w_1}\frac{\partial d_0}{\partial w_0}} \end{aligned}$$

Differentiating with respect to \(\theta\) we obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial t^*}{\partial \theta }=\frac{Q\frac{\partial q_1}{\partial w_1}\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial w_0}}{\frac{\partial q_0}{\partial w_0}\frac{\partial d_1}{\partial w_1}-\frac{\partial q_1}{\partial w_1}\frac{\partial d_0}{\partial w_0}}. \end{aligned}$$

Differentiating with respect to \(\gamma\) we get:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial t^*}{\partial \gamma }=\frac{\frac{\partial q_1}{\partial w_1}\frac{\partial D}{\partial w_0}}{\frac{\partial q_0}{\partial w_0}\frac{\partial d_1}{\partial w_1}-\frac{\partial q_1}{\partial w_1}\frac{\partial d_0}{\partial w_0}}. \end{aligned}$$

Since \(\frac{\partial q_1}{\partial w_1}>0\) and \(\frac{\partial q_0}{\partial w_0}\frac{\partial d_1}{\partial w_1}-\frac{\partial q_1}{\partial w_1}\frac{\partial d_0}{\partial w_0}>0\), it is clear that \(\frac{\partial t^*}{\partial \gamma }<0\) and \(\frac{\partial t^*}{\partial \theta }>0\) when \(\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial w_0}>0\) \(\square\)

Proof Corollary 4

Proof

Solving Proposition 4 for t, we have that:

$$\begin{aligned} t^*=\frac{\frac{\partial q_1}{\partial w_1}\left( \frac{\partial c_0}{\partial w_0}+d_0\frac{\partial t}{\partial w_0}+\theta Q\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial w_0}+\gamma \frac{\partial D}{\partial w_0}-q_0\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial w_0}\right) -\frac{\partial q_0}{\partial w_0}\left( \frac{\partial c_1}{\partial w_1}+d_1\frac{\partial t}{\partial w_1}-q_1\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial w_1}\right) }{\frac{\partial q_0}{\partial w_0}\frac{\partial d_1}{\partial w_1}-\frac{\partial q_1}{\partial w_1}\frac{\partial d_0}{\partial w_0}} \end{aligned}$$

It is straightforward to find each case. Just replace \(\theta\) and \(\gamma\) with the values of each case as follows.

Case i: \(\theta =\gamma =0\) \(\Longrightarrow\) \(t^*=\frac{\frac{\partial q_1}{\partial w_1}\left( \frac{\partial c_0}{\partial w_0}+d_0\frac{\partial t}{\partial w_0}-q_0\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial w_0}\right) -\frac{\partial q_0}{\partial w_0}\left( \frac{\partial c_1}{\partial w_1}+d_1\frac{\partial t}{\partial w_1}-q_1\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial w_1}\right) }{\frac{\partial q_0}{\partial w_0}\frac{\partial d_1}{\partial w_1}-\frac{\partial q_1}{\partial w_1}\frac{\partial d_0}{\partial w_0}}\)

Case ii: \(\theta >0\) and \(\gamma =0\) \(\Longrightarrow\) \(t^*=\frac{\frac{\partial q_1}{\partial w_1}\left( \frac{\partial c_0}{\partial w_0}+d_0\frac{\partial t}{\partial w_0}+\theta Q\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial w_0}-q_0\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial w_0}\right) -\frac{\partial q_0}{\partial w_0}\left( \frac{\partial c_1}{\partial w_1}+d_1\frac{\partial t}{\partial w_1}-q_1\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial w_1}\right) }{\frac{\partial q_0}{\partial w_0}\frac{\partial d_1}{\partial w_1}-\frac{\partial q_1}{\partial w_1}\frac{\partial d_0}{\partial w_0}}\)

Case iii: \(\theta =0\) and \(\gamma >0\) \(\Longrightarrow\) \(t^*=\frac{\frac{\partial q_1}{\partial w_1}\left( \frac{\partial c_0}{\partial w_0}+d_0\frac{\partial t}{\partial w_0}+\gamma \frac{\partial D}{\partial w_0}-q_0\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial w_0}\right) -\frac{\partial q_0}{\partial w_0}\left( \frac{\partial c_1}{\partial w_1}+d_1\frac{\partial t}{\partial w_1}-q_1\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial w_1}\right) }{\frac{\partial q_0}{\partial w_0}\frac{\partial d_1}{\partial w_1}-\frac{\partial q_1}{\partial w_1}\frac{\partial d_0}{\partial w_0}}\)

Case iv: \(\theta >0\) and \(\gamma >0\) \(\Longrightarrow\) \(t^*=\frac{\frac{\partial q_1}{\partial w_1}\left( \frac{\partial c_0}{\partial w_0}+d_0\frac{\partial t}{\partial w_0}+\theta Q\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial w_0}+\gamma \frac{\partial D}{\partial w_0}-q_0\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial w_0}\right) -\frac{\partial q_0}{\partial w_0}\left( \frac{\partial c_1}{\partial w_1}+d_1\frac{\partial t}{\partial w_1}-q_1\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial w_1}\right) }{\frac{\partial q_0}{\partial w_0}\frac{\partial d_1}{\partial w_1}-\frac{\partial q_1}{\partial w_1}\frac{\partial d_0}{\partial w_0}}\) \(\square\)

Output of a CSR Firm is Less than the Output of a Profit Maximizing Firm

Since we know that \(q_0=\frac{\frac{\partial c_0}{\partial q_0}+t\frac{\partial d_0}{\partial q_0}-f(Q)+\gamma \frac{\partial D}{\partial d_0}}{(1-\theta )\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_0}}+q_1\frac{\theta }{1-\theta }\), let’s show that production is greater when \(\theta =\gamma =0\) than when \(\theta >0\) and \(\gamma >0\). Then, it should be the case that:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\frac{\partial c_0}{\partial q_0}+t\frac{\partial d_0}{\partial q_0}-f(Q)}{\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_0}}>\frac{\frac{\partial c_0}{\partial q_0}+t\frac{\partial d_0}{\partial q_0}-f(Q)+\gamma \frac{\partial D}{\partial d_0}}{(1-\theta )\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_0}}+q_1\frac{\theta }{1-\theta } \end{aligned}$$

Proof

$$\begin{aligned}{} & {} (1-\theta )\frac{\partial c_0}{\partial q_0}+t(1-\theta )\frac{\partial d_0}{\partial q_0}-(1-\theta )f(Q)>\frac{\partial c_0}{\partial q_0}+t\frac{\partial d_0}{\partial q_0}-f(Q)+\gamma \frac{\partial D}{\partial d_0}+\theta q_1\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_0}\\{} & {} \Rightarrow f(Q)-\frac{\partial c_0}{\partial q_0}-t\frac{\partial d_0}{\partial q_0}>q_1\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_0} \end{aligned}$$

Since f(Q) is de inverse demand function, \(\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_0}<0\) (assuming normal goods), and therefore the right-hand side of the inequality is negative. However, we know that the reaction function of a firm without CSR motivations is \(q_i=\frac{\frac{\partial c_i}{\partial q_i}+t\frac{\partial d_i}{\partial q_i}-f(Q)}{\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_i}}>0\) (if not the case, the firm doesn’t produce). Then, because \(\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_0}<0\), it may be the case that \(\frac{\partial c_i}{\partial q_i}+t\frac{\partial d_i}{\partial q_i}-f(Q)<0\) \(\Leftrightarrow\) \(f(Q)-\frac{\partial c_i}{\partial q_i}-t\frac{\partial d_i}{\partial q_i}>0\), and therefore the left-hand side of the inequality is positive, then:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\frac{\partial c_0}{\partial q_0}+t\frac{\partial d_0}{\partial q_0}-f(Q)}{\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_0}}>\frac{\frac{\partial c_0}{\partial q_0}+t\frac{\partial d_0}{\partial q_0}-f(Q)+\gamma \frac{\partial D}{\partial d_0}}{(1-\theta )\frac{\partial f(Q)}{\partial q_0}}+q_1\frac{\theta }{1-\theta } \end{aligned}$$

\(\square\)

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Villena, M.G., Quinteros, M.J. Corporate Social Responsibility, Environmental Emissions and Time-Consistent Taxation. Environ Resource Econ 87, 219–255 (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-023-00822-1

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-023-00822-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation