Skip to main content

FDI-growth and trade-growth relationships during crises: evidence from Bangladesh

Abstract

This study examines foreign direct investment (FDI)-growth and trade-growth relationships in Bangladesh during three major crises: the economic crisis of 2007–2008, the commodity crisis of 2016, and the coronavirus (COVID-19) pandemic of 2020. The augmented autoregressive distributed lag (AARDL) bounds testing approach and Bayer and Hanck cointegration are employed on time-series data spanning the period 1974–2020. The results suggest that exports have positive effects on economic growth, while imports have insignificant effects in both the short run and long run. Total trade (the sum of exports and imports) has a positive but weakly significant effect on economic growth only in the long run, whereas FDI exhibits a positive effect in both the short run and long run. Although the crises are not found to affect economic growth directly or through trade (i.e., no dampening effect on trade-led growth), they are found to distort FDI-led growth in both the short run and long run. As robustness tests for long-run elasticities, the fully modified ordinary least squares (FMOLS) and dynamic ordinary least squares (DOLS) cointegration techniques are implemented, yielding results similar to those obtained with the AARDL.

Introduction

A general consensus among academics and policymakers is that foreign direct investment (FDI) and international trade act as, among others, the major drivers of economic growth in developing countries. As a result, FDI-growth and trade-growth relationships have been extensively investigated in the growth-related empirical literature. In the second half of the last century, particularly in the 1970s, research was centered on strategies regarding either import substitution or export promotion of manufactured products (Voivodas 1973; Williamson 1978). Moving into the 1980s and 1990s, export-led growth received extensive attention from researchers (Balassa 1985; Feder 1983). Additionally, some studies have also examined the effects of imports and total trade (the sum of exports and imports) on economic growth (Deme 2002; Gómez et al. 2011).

Since 1990, the international financial market has witnessed increasing FDI flows. Foreign capital plays a substantial role in accelerating economic growth in countries that lack sufficient domestic savings—both private and public—and depend heavily on external finance for industrial expansion (Sarker and Khan 2020). Consequently, many developing countries have liberalized their financial policies to attract FDI.Footnote 1 The major driving force behind global FDI flows has been the prospect of lower production costs (Bevan et al. 2004). Given that developing countries can offer labor and other factors of production at low costs, they have attracted a considerable portion of global FDI flows, although developed countries have traditionally received the lion’s share.

However, crises may have dampening effects on international trade and FDI inflows due to shrinking aggregate demand and increasing uncertainty in macroeconomic performance, respectively (Ucal et al. 2010). The world total trade (the sum of exports and imports) declined by 13% in 2009 and by 9% in 2020 because of the 2007 economic crisis and the 2020 coronavirus (COVID-19) pandemic, respectively. The 2016 commodity crisis resulted in a less severe reduction in world trade (World Bank 2021). Following the economic crisis of 2007, global FDI flows fell by 16% in 2008, global output contracted in 2009, and FDI declined further by 40% in 2010 (Poulsen and Hufbauer 2011). Falling commodity prices in 2016 reduced global FDI flows by 13% and slowed economic growth, although the declines were not equally distributed across regions (UNCTAD 2017). According to a recent report, global FDI flows fell by 42% in 2020 due to the COVID-19 pandemic (UNCTAD 2021a). In Bangladesh, the decline in total trade was 2% in 2009 and 13% in 2020, whereas the effect of the 2016 commodity crisis on trade was less severe. The Bangladesh economy experienced a 36% fall in FDI inflows between 2008 and 2009, an 8% fall between 2016 and 2017, and an 11% fall between 2019 and 2020 (UNCTAD 2017).

Therefore, it is evident that crises negatively affect both international trade and FDI inflows. This fact naturally leads researchers to ask whether crises affect economic growth through their dampening effects on trade and FDI inflows. Some studies have investigated the crisis-FDI relationship (Dornean et al. 2012; Mahmoud 2011; Ucal et al. 2010) and the crisis-trade relationship (Chor and Manova 2012; Curran et al. 2009; Macias et al. 2010). Some other studies have connected crises and economic growth through either FDI inflows (Asteriou and Spanos 2019; Gaies et al. 2019; Jimborean and Kelber 2017) or trade (Liu et al. 2019; Yuan et al. 2010) and found mixed results, with some finding stimulating and others finding a dampening effects of crises on FDI-growth and trade-growth relationships. The study by Asteriou and Spanos (2019) was the first to consider both trade and FDI in assessing the effects of crises on economic growth in 26 European Union (EU) countries and found a distortionary effect of crises on economic growth through FDI and a stimulating effect through trade.

However, most of the aforementioned studies are centered on European countries, with a few investigating Latin American and East Asian countries. To the best of my knowledge, no study has examined crisis-FDI-growth or crisis-trade-growth relationships in South Asian countries or Bangladesh. Since countries in different regions have different economic settings in terms of infrastructural challenges, trade openness, economic policies, financial markets, and so forth (Sarker and Serieux 2023), the findings of previous studies cannot be generalized to all countries. Hence, the study of FDI-growth and trade-growth relationships incorporating the effects of crises demands further empirical research. Since the ratio of trade to GDP in Bangladesh—an emerging economy in Asia—has exceeded 40% in recent decades and the economy depends significantly on FDI inflows for mobilizing capital investment, the recent crises might have significantly affected the economy through these two channels.Footnote 2 Hence, it is important to examine whether the global crises affected economic growth in Bangladesh by influencing foreign trade and FDI inflows.

This study investigates whether global crises affected FDI-growth and trade-growth relationships in Bangladesh. The contribution of this study is that along with the 2007–2008 economic crisis and the 2016 commodity crisis, it considers the COVID-19 pandemic, which has not yet been incorporated into the related literature. Since the current world is characterized by globalization and a liberalized economic system in which restrictions on the movement of goods and capital are being continuously relaxed, any economic or financial shock to major economies or the global economy may have a direct or indirect impact on other economies. Although these three crises are not similar in terms of nature and impacts on economic outcomes, they are expected to affect the economic growth trajectory of Bangladesh through various channels.Footnote 3 Therefore, this study might serve as the basis for future studies on the indirect impacts of crises or external shocks in other countries. Results reveal that the lobal crises had a distorting effect on FDI-led growth in both the short run and long run but had no effect on trade-led growth.

The rest of the paper proceeds as follows. Sect. “Theory and related literature” provides the theoretical underpinnings and related literature. Sect. “Methodology and data” describes the methodology and data sources. Sect. “Results and discussion” presents the results and discussion, and Sect. “Conclusion and policy recommendations” concludes the paper.

Theory and related literature

FDI-led growth

The Solow spirit of growth model argues that FDI engenders growth by accumulating capital and incorporating new inputs and foreign technologies in the production processes of recipient economies (Dunning 1970; Krueger 1987; Todaro 1982). The neoclassical growth theory assumes that FDI can channel the required funds to the deserving sectors of a capital-shortage country and increase the marginal productivity of capital, thus stimulating economic growth. Specifically, the neoclassical growth theory states that an economy requires a long-term capital commitment to flourish persistently (Adams 2009). Since FDI is a source of long-term and reliable capital for developing economies, economists emphasize its efficacy in augmenting economic growth.

The endogenous growth theory, on the other hand, maintains that a country’s long-run growth is affected by physical investment and the efficacy of its utilization. It has been argued that FDI brings organizational, managerial, and technical skills as well as improved technology (Lucas 1988; Romer 1986), augments the stock of knowledge and skills, and spills over externalities to recipient economies (Grossman and Helpman 1991). Thus, FDI is expected to fuel economic growth by reducing the capital gap, partly offsetting research and development (R&D) investment, creating new job opportunities in host economies (Borensztein et al. 1998; Sarker 2023), and reducing the technological gap between national and international enterprises (Anwar and Nguyen 2010; Sarker and Serieux 2022). However, in recipient countries with low levels of human capital and weak technology absorption capacity, the impact of FDI on production is inadequate (Forte and Moura 2013).

The empirical literature has presented evidence supporting the role of FDI in fostering economic growth in recipient economies (Popescu 2014; Shan 2002); however, there is evidence of no significant effect as well (Alvarado et al. 2017). Using data on 15 East Asian economies, Kotrajaras et al. (2011) revealed that the favorable impacts of FDI depend on each host country’s economic conditions, such as the development levels of financial markets and institutions, better governance, and suitable macroeconomic policies.

Trade-led growth

For more than a century, economic analysts have debated the association between trade policies and economic performance. The modernization theory—originating from the ideas of Max Weber and later developed by Talcott Parsons—opines that trade openness facilitates the transformation of developing economies from a pre-modern stage to a modern and civilized stage via trade with developed economies. Similarly, Ricardo (1817) hypothesized the comparative advantage theory, which states that an economy should specialize in the production and export of commodities with lower opportunity costs and import commodities with comparatively higher opportunity costs. The Heckscher–Ohlin model of international trade states that a capital-abundant (labor-abundant) country should specialize in the production and export of capital-intensive (labor-intensive) products. The neoclassical theory maintains that trade expansion is, among others, the major driver of economic growth.

Arthur Lewis, in his pioneering work “Theory of Economic Growth,” argued that countries that have trade relationships with the rest of the world have an advantage in absorbing technological innovations generated in advanced countries. In the past three decades, the rapid growth in newly industrialized nations has motivated other less developed countries to change their trade policies in favor of more liberalized trade regimes. Supporters of liberal economies argue that freer trade results in faster economic growth,Footnote 4 while protectionists argue that trade restrictions may ensure better economic performance. Consequently, the association between international trade and economic growth has been extensively examined in both the theoretical and empirical literature.Footnote 5 The empirical literature has revealed a significant effect of trade on economic growth (e.g., Deme 2002; Zahonogo 2017).

The endogenous growth theory recognizes the role of imports as an engine for long-run economic growth as well as export expansion as imports provide domestic firms with access to essential intermediate inputs and upgraded technology (Coe and Helpman 1995). In this regard, Lawrence and Weinstein (1999) and Mazumdar (2001) argued that imports may serve as a channel of R&D knowledge transfer from developed to developing countries. In most empirical studies, imports have been found to stimulate economic growth—import-led growth (Mahadevan 2007), although there is also evidence of a negative effect (Jawaid 2014).

Supporters of the export-led growth hypothesis argue that exports induce economic growth by providing countries with foreign exchange that allows for more imports of intermediate goods and advanced machinery (Bhagwati 1988; Edwards 1998). Helpman and Krugman (1985) stressed that exports expedite economic growth in a country by achieving economies of scale—specialization of production and dissemination of technical knowledge—and better allocation of resources. It is also argued that export expansion allows for specialization based on comparative advantage (Mahadevan 2007) and leads to rapid expansion of employment and real wages (Athukorala and Menon 1996). Thus, growth in exports increases productivity in exporting sectors and stimulates higher domestic spending, which is another source of GDP growth. The export-led growth literature has produced evidence supporting the idea that exports play a stimulating role in economic growth (Kavoussi 1984; McNab and Moore 1998).

Transmission of crises

Rapid globalization has made global markets increasingly interconnected, particularly with respect to international trade and cross-border financial flows. Thus, trade and financial linkages are two big channels through which crises are immediately transmitted across borders (Alfaro et al. 2004). The transmission of economic shocks from one economy or region to others—economic contagion—becomes quicker as economic integration among countries strengthens. The transmission of economic crises can be explained by theories related to FDI and trade, such as the theories of economic contagion, demand shocks and supply disruptions, and risk aversion. These theories can be classified into two broad groups: those that explain fundamental causes and those that are linked to investors’ behavior (Bandara 2014).

Crises and FDI inflows

A healthy economy with sound economic growth and employment rates attracts foreign investors. Crises may lead to a reduction in FDI flows by influencing various macroeconomic indicators such as economic performance and productivity (Saleh 2023). The financial contagion theory states that economic crises can spread across countries through financial channels, including FDI. Crises force foreign investors to reconsider their cross-border investments. Crisis-hit countries experience financial shocks and instability, which, in turn, can cause foreign investors to lose confidence and withdraw their investments and operations from those countries, also known as “escaping behavior” (Gorg and Strobl 2003). The withdrawal of FDI may amplify a country’s crisis by further destabilizing the economy and affecting the availability of investible funds.

The underlying mechanism of financial contagion can be explained by a decline in demand and an increase in costs. Crises reduce demand, thus effecting a decline in sales (Alfaro and Chen 2010). A decline in sales leads to low production and low profits or even losses, eventually decreasing FDI inflows (Urata and Kawai 2000). In addition, crises often cause inflation, higher exchange rates, and increased transaction costs for foreign investors (Alegre and Sard 2015). These increased costs compel multinational enterprises to reassess their partnerships with local firms and seek tighter control over firms’ operations, making it hard to find local partners (Williams and Martinez 2012).

Risk aversion theories state that the global investment climate is frequently risky and unpredictable during economic crises. Investors may become more cautious and risk-averse when they are unsure of the economic and political circumstances of a nation in crisis. They might decide to invest in safer places, postpone or cancel planned FDI initiatives, or do both (Hosseini 2005). This decline in FDI can negatively impact crisis-hit economies, leading to job losses and slowing down economic growth (Asteriou and Spanos 2019). However, the extent to which crises have a negative effect on FDI inflows depends on the economic performance of the crisis-hit economy.

Crises and trade

Crises can affect an economy’s trade through various channels, such as demand shocks, supply disruptions, and exchange rate fluctuations. For instance, economic crises frequently result in a decrease in business and consumer confidence, thus lowering the demand for goods and services (Klapper and Love 2011). This fall in demand in turn exerts a significant influence on global trade (Auboin and Engemann 2014). Reduced demand from crisis-hit nations can affect trading partners and lower trade volumes; these changes reverberate across global supply chains. Similarly, economic crises can alter trade flows by disrupting global supply chains. Production disruptions and shortages of intermediate goods might result from crises in major exporting nations or important suppliers (Blome and Schoenherr 2011). These interruptions may spread through supply chains and affect the ability of other nations to produce and export goods (Chongvilaivan 2012). As businesses struggle to find essential materials, trade volumes may fall, causing the crisis to spread through trade channels.

A crisis can lead to currency devaluation, thus reducing the demand for imports due to reduced income and lowering the international export competitiveness of other countries (Bilbao-Ubillos and Fernández-Sainz 2022). In contrast, exports may become more competitive as a result of currency devaluation, which can enhance export volumes in the crisis-hit country and reduce trading partners’ export competitiveness. This fall in exports in other countries depresses their GDP growth by affecting production, which, in turn, reduces their import demand (Yuan et al. 2010). Therefore, exchange rate changes during economic crises may have an impact on international trade flows. After the 2007 economic crisis, export growth fell from 6.7% in 2007 to 2.9% in 2008 and − 9.9% in 2009; import growth fell from 7.6% in 2007 to 3.2% in 2008 and − 11.6% in 2009 (World Bank 2021). Due to the COVID-19 crisis, export and import growth sharply fell from 1.1% and 1.7% in 2019 to − 9.0% and − 9.3% in 2020, respectively (World Bank 2021). Trade openness, on the other hand, can also stimulate economic growth of some economies during crises because countries may further liberalize trade policies as part of a reform package (Asteriou and Spanos 2019; Liu et al. 2019).

Therefore, crises tend to affect countries that heavily depend on foreign investment for restructuring and industrializing their economies and whose trade volume constitutes a substantial part of their GDP. Foreign investors may invest less in the event of declining demand and evolving uncertainty resulting from crises. For example, after the economic crisis emerged in 2007, global FDI flows significantly reduced from a record high of US$ 1.91 trillion in 2007 to US$ 1.49 trillion in 2008 and US$ 1.24 trillion in 2009. After the 2016 commodity price shock, FDI flow started falling again, from US$ 2.07 trillion in 2016 to 1.44 trillion in 2018. Further, following the COVID-19 crisis at the beginning of 2020, it decreased sharply, reaching 1 trillion in 2020—a record low after 2005 (UNCTAD 2021b). The decreasing flow of foreign capital led to a shortage of investible funds and a subsequent decline in production and GDP growth (Asteriou and Spanos 2019; Breitenlechner et al. 2015). However, there is evidence of FDI accelerating economic growth during crises (Gaies et al. 2019; Jimborean and Kelber 2017).

Bangladesh, being a developing country, heavily depends on foreign trade and FDI inflows as instruments of rapid economic growth. The economy encountered a similar sharp fall in export and import growth after both the 2007 economic crisis and COVID-19 crisis, while the economy experienced a different trend in FDI inflows compared with global FDI flows. Due to the nature of the economy and composition of GDP, any negative shocks in trade, particularly in exports, and FDI inflows resulting from any uncertainty are likely to have dampening effects on FDI-growth and trade-growth relationships. Thus, it is worth investigating whether the crises that are considered in this study had any direct negative effect on economic growth or an indirect dampening effect on FDI-growth and trade-growth relationships in Bangladesh.

Methodology and data

Model specification

The hypothesis tested in this study is whether the considered three crises affected FDI-growth and trade-growth relationships in Bangladesh. The model is built on the standard Cobb–Douglas production function and is distinctly augmented, including FDI inflows, exports, imports, total trade, real capital stock, labor force, broad money (M3),Footnote 6 and crises. The function is expressed as follows:

$$Q_{t} = A_{t} L_{t}^{\alpha } K_{t}^{1 - \alpha } ;\quad \quad 0 < \alpha < 1$$
(1)

where \(Q_{t}\) denotes real output, L labor force, and K real capital stock. A denotes technological progress, which is assumed to vary over time. Following Kumar and Paramanik (2020), Dritsaki and Stamatiou (2018), and Okere et al. (2022), among others, technological progress is considered a function of trade, FDI inflows, and broad money (M3). Thus, A is defined as follows:

$$A_{t} = {\uppsi }.TR_{t}^{\beta } FDI_{t}^{\gamma } M3_{t}^{\delta }$$
(2)

where \(TR_{t}\) indicates total trade (the sum of exports and imports) and \(M3_{t}\) is used as an indicator of financial depth (i.e., the size of the financial sector). The argument is that a large and developed financial market and the availability of finance stimulate economic growth through multiple channels, including manufacturing growth. The inclusion of this variable also lowers the risk of falling prey to omitted variable bias. \({\uppsi }\) is a time-invariant constant. Therefore, the production function in Eq. (1) becomes:

$$Q_{t} = {\uppsi }.TR_{t}^{\beta } FDI_{t}^{\gamma } M3_{t}^{\delta } L_{t}^{\alpha } K_{t}^{1 - \alpha }$$
(3)

The log transformation of Eq. (3) will be as follows:

$$lnQ_{t} = \theta_{0} + \beta lnTR_{t} + \gamma lnFDI_{t} + \delta lnM3_{t} + \alpha lnL_{t} + \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)lnK_{t} + \varepsilon_{t}$$
(4)

where \(ln{\uppsi } = \theta_{0}\), and \(\varepsilon_{t}\) is the white-noise error term. Further, the model is augmented by introducing a dummy variable that accounts for the three crises and their interaction terms with FDI and trade as follows:

$$lnQ_{t} = \theta_{0} + \beta lnT\!R_{t} + \gamma lnF\!DI_{t} + \delta lnM3_{t} + \alpha lnL_{t} + \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)lnK_{t} + \eta C_{t} + \theta_{1} \left(C \times lnT\!R \right)_{t} + \theta_{2} \left(C \times lnF\!DI \right)_{t} + \varepsilon_{t}$$
(5)

where \(C_{t}\) denotes crises, which is a dummy variable that takes a value of 1 for the years 2007, 2008, 2009, 2016, 2017, and 2020 and 0 for all other years. Real GDP (\(lnQ_{t}\)) is simply the yearly aggregate output in Bangladesh taken as the 2010 constant US$ value. To capture the individual effect of trade on economic growth amidst crises, total trade is decomposed into exports and imports. The sign and significance of the coefficients of the interaction terms (\(\theta_{1}\) and \(\theta_{2}\)) explain how crises affect economic growth through FDI inflows and international trade.

Labor force (lnL) and capital stock (lnK) are indispensable parts of the Cobb–Douglas type of production function due to their contribution to total output. They have been widely used in research on FDI-growth and trade-growth relationships. Although a large body of empirical literature has used gross fixed capital formation as a channel for engendering growth, real capital stock, generated from gross fixed capital formation (GFCF) using the perpetual inventory model, is used in this study as an appropriate measure of capital. Following the extant literature (Akinlo 2004; Vadlamannati and Tamazian 2009), real capital stock is generated based on the following formula:

$$K_{t} = \left( {1 - \delta } \right)K_{t - 1} + I_{t}$$
(6)

\(K_{t}\), in Eq. (6), is the real capital stock in year t, \(K_{t - 1}\) is the real capital stock in year \(t - 1\) (previous year), and \(I_{t}\) is the real investment in year t (defined as gross fixed capital formation measured in the 2010 US$ constant value; e.g., Akram and Rath 2018). The symbol, \(\delta\), is the capital depreciation rate for Bangladesh economy. The initial capital stock is defined as follows:

$$K_{0} = I_{0} /\left( {g + \delta } \right)$$
(7)

where \(K_{0}\) is initial capital stock, \(I_{0}\) is initial capital investment, \(\delta\) is as defined before, and g is the average growth rate of capital investment used to generate the initial capital stock for the considered period of this study. Following similar modeling in the empirical literature (e.g., Adeleye et al. 2021; Adusei and Adeleye 2020), the interaction coefficients (\(\theta_{1}\) and \(\theta_{2}\)) can be interpreted as follows:

  • If \(\theta_{1} = 0\) and \(\theta_{2} = 0\), it implies that the interaction of crises with trade and FDI inflows has no significant effect on economic growth.

  • If \(\theta_{1} > 0\) and \(\theta_{2} > 0\), crises boost economic growth.

  • If \(\theta_{1} < 0\) and \(\theta_{2} < 0\), the overall impact of trade and FDI inflows on economic growth depends on the magnitude of the negative coefficient.

  • If the negative sign of \(\theta_{1}\) and \(\theta_{2}\) outweighs the positive sign of \(\beta\) and \(\gamma\), crises distort the impact of trade and FDI inflows on economic growth.

  • If the negative sign of \(\theta_{1}\) and \(\theta_{2}\) is less than the positive sign of \(\beta\) and \(\gamma\), the distortionary influence of crises is not sufficient to inhibit the positive effects of trade and FDI inflows on economic growth.

Estimation technique

Augmented autoregressive distributed lag bounds test

Goh and McNown (2015) demonstrated that reporting only the F-test for overall significance and the t-test on the lagged dependent variable in the autoregressive distributed lag (ARDL) bounds testing model is insufficient and may lead to degenerate case 1 pointed out by Pesaran et al. (2001).Footnote 7 To avoid this problem, McNown et al. (2018) proposed an additional t-test or F-test on the lagged levels of independent variables in the ARDL model and named it “augmented ARDL” (AARDL). Therefore, all three tests should be conducted and reported to distinguish between evidence of cointegration and degenerate cases. Hence, the AARDL bounds testing approach to cointegration proposed by McNown et al. (2018) is applied in this study to investigate FDI-growth and trade-growth relationships.

This method is flexible in terms of application because it allows data series to be of a different order of integration—a mixture of zero-order integration (I(0)) and first-order integration (I(1))—whereas other cointegration methods, such as those proposed by Engle and Granger (1987), Johansen (1988), and Johansen and Juselius (1990), require all variables to be I(1).Footnote 8 However, AARDL is not applicable if any variable is I(2). This method provides consistent estimates for a small dataset as well (Haug 2002) and offers more options for selecting lag for both dependent and independent variables while simultaneously handling endogeneity problems in variables. For our considered framework, this model can be specified as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta lnQ_{t} & = \alpha_{0} + \mathop \sum \limits_{i = 1}^{m} \beta_{1i} \Delta lnQ_{t - i} + \mathop \sum \limits_{i = 0}^{n} \beta_{2i} \Delta lnTR_{t - i} + \mathop \sum \limits_{i = 0}^{p} \beta_{3i} \Delta lnL_{t - 1} + \mathop \sum \limits_{i = 0}^{q} \beta_{4i} \Delta lnK_{t - i} \\ & \quad + \mathop \sum \limits_{i = 0}^{r} \beta_{5i} \Delta lnM3_{t - i} + \mathop \sum \limits_{i = 0}^{n} \beta_{6i} \Delta\left( { C \times lnTR} \right)_{t - i} + \gamma_{1} lnQ_{t - 1} + \gamma_{2} lnTR_{t - 1} + \gamma_{3} lnL_{t - 1} \\ & \quad \qquad \qquad + \gamma_{4} lnK_{t - 1} + \gamma_{5} lnM3_{t - 1} + \theta_{1} C_{t - 1} + \theta_{2} \left( { C \times lnTR} \right)_{t - 1} + \varepsilon_{t} \\ \end{aligned}$$
(8)
$$\begin{aligned} \Delta lnQ_{t} & = \alpha_{0} + \mathop \sum \limits_{i = 1}^{m} \beta_{1i} \Delta lnQ_{t - i} + \mathop \sum \limits_{i = 0}^{n} \beta_{2i} \Delta lnFDI_{t - i} + \mathop \sum \limits_{i = 0}^{p} \beta_{3i} \Delta lnL_{t - 1} + \mathop \sum \limits_{i = 0}^{q} \beta_{4i} \Delta lnK_{t - i} \\ & + \mathop \sum \limits_{i = 0}^{r} \beta_{5i} \Delta lnM3_{t - i} + \mathop \sum \limits_{i = 0}^{n} \beta_{6i} \Delta \left( {C \times lnFDI} \right)_{t - i} + \gamma_{1} lnQ_{t - 1} + \gamma_{2} lnTR_{t - 1} + \gamma_{3} lnL_{t - 1} \\ & \qquad\qquad \qquad+ \gamma_{4} lnK_{t - 1} + \gamma_{5} lnM3_{t - 1} + \theta_{1} C_{t - 1} + \theta_{2} \left( {C \times lnFDI} \right)_{t - 1} + \varepsilon_{t} \\ \end{aligned}$$
(9)

where \(\Delta\) is the first difference operator, and \(\varepsilon_{t}\) is the white-noise error term. In Eqs. (8) and (9), the terms with summation indicate short-run dynamics, while those without summation represent long-run effects. \(C_{t - 1}\) in both equations is a dummy variable accounting for the effects of the three crises considered in this study. The null hypothesis is that there is no level relationship in the long run and no effect of the crises, i.e., the corresponding coefficients are zero.

In this study, two sets of asymptotic critical values provided by Pesaran et al. (2001) and Sam et al. (2019) are considered—one for I(0) series and another for I(1) series. When the value of the F-test on overall significance is less than the lower-bound critical value and the absolute value of the t-test is lower than the absolute lower-bound critical value, the null hypothesis of “no long-run relationship” cannot be rejected. On the contrary, when the value of the F-test is greater than the upper-bound critical value and the absolute value of the t-test is greater than the absolute upper-bound critical value, the null hypothesis is rejected, indicating long-run relationships between the variables. However, if the values of the test statistics are neither less than nor greater than the lower-bound and upper-bound critical values, respectively, the decision regarding long-run relationships is inconclusive.

The following error correction models are used to analyze the short-run dynamics.

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta lnQ_{t} & = \alpha_{0} + \mathop \sum \limits_{i = 1}^{m} \beta_{1i} \Delta lnQ_{t - i} + \mathop \sum \limits_{i = 0}^{n} \beta_{2i} \Delta lnTR_{t - i} + \mathop \sum \limits_{i = 0}^{p} \beta_{3i} \Delta lnL_{t - 1} + \mathop \sum \limits_{i = 0}^{q} \beta_{4i} \Delta lnK_{t - i} \\ & \quad + \mathop \sum \limits_{i = 0}^{r} \beta_{5i} \Delta lnM3_{t - i} + \mathop \sum \limits_{i = 0}^{n} \beta_{6i} \Delta \left( {C \times lnTR} \right)_{t - i} + \theta_{1} C_{t - 1} + \omega_{1} EC_{t - 1} + \tau_{t} \\ \end{aligned}$$
(10)
$$\begin{aligned} \Delta lnQ_{t} & = \alpha_{0} + \mathop \sum \limits_{i = 1}^{m} \beta_{1i} \Delta lnQ_{t - i} + \mathop \sum \limits_{i = 0}^{n} \beta_{2i} \Delta lnFDI_{t - i} + \mathop \sum \limits_{i = 0}^{p} \beta_{3i} \Delta lnL_{t - 1} + \mathop \sum \limits_{i = 0}^{q} \beta_{4i} \Delta lnK_{t - i} \\ & \quad \quad \, + \mathop \sum \limits_{i = 0}^{r} \beta_{5i} \Delta lnM3_{t - i} + \mathop \sum \limits_{i = 0}^{n} \beta_{6i} \Delta \left( {C \times lnFDI} \right)_{t - i} + \theta_{1} C_{t - 1} + \omega_{2} EC_{t - 1} + \tau_{t} \\ \end{aligned}$$
(11)

where the coefficients (\(\beta_{si}\)) indicate short-run dynamics. The term EC denotes error correction, measuring each period’s speed of adjustment toward equilibrium after a shock, and \(\omega_{1}\) and \(\omega_{2}\) are the corresponding parameters. The expected value of \(\omega_{s}\) is \(- 1 \le \omega_{s} \le 0\), where a value of 0 implies no convergence and − 1 denotes perfect convergence, i.e., any shock in the current period is perfectly adjusted in the next period. Several diagnostic tests are implemented to demonstrate the validity of the used model. First, the Harvey F-test determines whether the residuals of the model are homoscedastic. Second, the Breusch–Godfrey LM test checks for serial correlation. Third, the Ramsey RESET test assesses model specification. Fourth, the Jarque–Bera test is used to check for the normality of the residuals of the model. Finally, the plots of the cumulative sum (CUSUM) and CUSUM of squares tests indicate the stability of the models and estimated parameters.

Robustness tests

To check for the robustness of the estimated cointegration results, this study employs the Bayer and Hanck (2013) cointegration test. The Bayer and Hanck cointegration test facilitates an improved power of estimates that is based on methods outlined by Banerjee et al. (1998), Boswijk (1995), Johansen (1991), and Engle and Granger (1987). It combines the individual cointegration test results and incorporates the computed significance level (p-value) of these four tests. This test is built on Fisher’s equation, as illustrated by Bekun et al. (2019), as follows:

$$EG - JOH = - 2\left[ {\ln \left( {P_{EG} } \right) + ln(P_{JOH} )} \right]$$
(12)
$$EG - JOH - BO - BDM = - 2\left[ {\ln \left( {P_{EG} } \right) + ln(P_{JOH} ) + ln(P_{BO} ) + ln(P_{BDM} )} \right]$$
(13)

where EG, JOH, BO, and BDM indicate Engle and Granger (1987), Johansen (1991), Boswijk (1995), and Banerjee et al. (1998) tests, respectively, and \(P_{EG}\), \(P_{JOH}\), \(P_{BO}\), and \(P_{BDM}\) are their respective levels of significance. The null hypothesis of “no cointegration” is rejected if the estimated test statistics exceed the critical values provided by Bayer and Hanck (2013). The fully modified ordinary least squares (FMOLS) and dynamic ordinary least squares (DOLS) tests are utilized to confirm the robustness of the AARDL long-run results.

Data

The data employed are annual time series for 47 years, ranging from 1974 to 2020. The period before 1974 is excluded because of missing values in the dataset.Footnote 9 The data on GDP, exports of goods and services, imports of goods and services, total trade (the sum of exports and imports), gross domestic capital formation, gross fixed capital formation, and broad money (M3) are all extracted as 2010 US$ constant values. The labor force indicates the total number of working-age people, i.e., people aged between 14 and 64 years. These data are drawn from the World Bank’s World Development Indicators (WDI) database. Data on FDI inflows are obtained from the UNCTAD database and converted to 2010 US$ constant values using the GDP deflator (which is taken from the WDI). The capital depreciation rate is taken from the Penn World Table version 10.0. All data, except the labor force, are in millions of US$. Refer to Table 9 in the appendix for the definitions of variables.

Bangladesh presents an interesting setting for investigating the research question as it has demonstrated stability in major macroeconomic variables and persistent growth in GDP for many years. The economy, for example, has recorded stable GDP growth of above 5%, which primarily results from developed microcredit programs and garment industries. In terms of foreign trade, Bangladesh inherited a policy of import-substituting industrialization with import protection and a pegged exchange rate (Yunus and Yamagata 2014). These policies started to change in the late 1970s with deregulation and limited trade liberalization as part of an export-oriented industrialization policy. Since the beginning of the 1990s, trade policies have been amended in favor of more liberalization with a managed floating exchange rate. IMF and World Bank guidelines accelerated the pace of trade liberalization policies, with a view to adopt an export-led growth strategy in the country.

To promote exports, the Bangladesh government invested heavily in improving trade infrastructure and established the Export Processing Zone Authority (BEPZA) in 1980, under which many export processing and economic zones were created. Numerous incentives have been provided to attract foreign investment in these zones, such as tax holidays for 5 years and the banning of labor unions, etc. A Special Bonded Warehouse SchemeFootnote 10 has been implemented, to allow firms to produce exclusively for export and to import duty-free inputs; further, a Duty Drawback System has been introduced to provide some duty-free inputs or rebates on duty levied on imported inputs for exporters (Dawson 2006). The Board of Investment (BOI) was established in 1989 and later merged with the Bangladesh Investment Development Authority (BIDA), formed in 2016, to promote and facilitate private investment. Moreover, to increase the inflow of foreign capital, the Bangladesh government gradually lifted restrictions on capital and profit repatriation and opened up almost all industries to foreign investment (Adhikary 2011).

Figure 1 displays time-series plots of real GDP and its growth rate, exports, imports, total trade, and FDI inflow. As it shows, real GDP has been steadily growing and at a faster pace after 2000. The growth rate of GDP has been hovering around 5% since 1990 and has gone above that since 2005. It declined after 2007 and went up again in 2010. In 2020, the growth rate fell sharply due to the COVID-19 crisis. The levels of exports and imports were low before 2000, and both started increasing sharply in 2003 with little fluctuation. Total trade (the sum of exports and imports) followed the same trend as exports and imports. FDI inflow was insignificant before 1995; it started rising thereafter owing to the financial deregulation in favor of liberalization.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Time-series representation of the main variables

Table 1 displays the descriptive statistics of the main variables of this study. All variables, except the labor force, are in million US$ units. There is significant variation among variables, as indicated by the standard deviation. The values of skewness are less than 1 for most of the variables, implying a moderately skewed distribution. For three variables—GDP, capital, and M3—the skewness values are slightly more than 1. The values of kurtosis for all variables, except labor force, are greater than 2, and for GDP and capital, it is greater than 3. A variable with a kurtosis value of 3 is considered to have a normal distribution (the Eviews 12 student version is used in the analysis).

Table 1 Descriptive statistics of the main variables

Results and discussion

Unit root results

As the ARDL bounds test suggests, variables must be integrated of order 0, I(0), or 1, I(1) in order to be cointegrated. To check for the order of integration of variables, two linear unit root tests—Dickey–Fuller generalized least squares (DF-GLS) proposed by Elliott et al. (1996) and Kwiatkowski–Phillips–Schmidt–Shin (KPSS) proposed by Kwiatkowski et al. (1992)—and one nonlinear unit root test, Kapetanios–Shin–Shell (KSS) proposed by Kapetanios et al. (2003), have been employed. The KSS test is used to accommodate the possibility of nonlinear dynamics in some series. Kapetanios et al. (2003) extended the ADF test based on an exponential smooth transition autoregressive process and introduced a new unit root test to check for linear unit roots against a nonlinear stationary process. As the stationary test results reported in Table 2 suggest, all variables are either I(0) or I(1), which provides a basis for applying the AARDL bounds testing approach as other cointegration tests that require all variables to be I(1), such as those used in Engle and Granger (1987) and Johansen (1988), are not applicable.

Table 2 Stationarity test results

AARDL cointegration results

The results of the AARDL bounds test estimation are reported in Table 3. The Akaike information criterion (AIC) is used to select the optimal lag length for each variable. Different lag lengths for each variable are selected across specifications, with the highest lag length being 3 and the lowest being 0. Although 7 specifications are estimated, specifications 4–7 are of interest as they include the interaction terms of crises with trade and FDI.

Table 3 AARDL bound testing with F-test and t-test

In all specifications (a “constant only” model), the values of the overall F-test (for the overall significance) exceed the upper-bound critical values at the 1% significance level, and the absolute values of the t-test on the lagged dependent variable exceed the absolute upper-bound critical values at the 1% significance level. The significance of these two test statistics indicates a long-run cointegrating relationship among the variables. To avoid degenerate case 1, as mentioned in Sect. “Augmented autoregressive distributed lag bounds test”, the values of the F-test on the lagged independent variables are also reported, which are all significant at the 1% level. These results mean that the lagged dependent variable is not the only source of the significance of the overall F-test; rather, lagged independent variables are a significant part of this (i.e., independent variables significantly affect the dependent variable, lnGDP), implying that there are long-run cointegrating relationships among the variables.

The diagnostic test results are also reported in Table 3. All specifications have a high value of adjusted R2. The Durbin–Watson test for autocorrelation indicates that there is no autocorrelation in the residuals as its value is approximately 2 in all specifications.Footnote 11 To reconfirm autocorrelation, the Breusch–Godfrey LM test statistic is reported, indicating that the null hypothesis of “no autocorrelation” cannot be rejected. To test for heteroscedasticity in the residuals, the Harvey test is reported, which cannot reject the null hypothesis of “homoscedastic residuals.” The Ramsey RESET test is utilized to indicate the stability of the model and estimated parameters. The value of the F-statistic in the Ramsey RESET test is not significant, which implies that there is no model misspecification, and the estimated parameters are stable. Lastly, the Jarque–Bera normality test indicates that all models have a normal distribution as the null of the “normal distribution” cannot be rejected.

Table 4 reports the long-run elasticities of GDP with respect to the explanatory variables. As it shows, exports have a significant positive effect on economic growth (e.g., Balassa 1985; McNab and Moore 1998), whereas imports have a negative and insignificant coefficient (e.g., the study by Awokuse (2007) on Bulgaria and Poland and the study by Aluko and Adeyeye (2020) on 29 African countries). Moreover, trade (the sum of exports and imports) has an overall positive impact on GDP (e.g., Deme 2002; Zahonogo 2017). Notably, FDI exerts a significant positive impact on GDP (e.g., Alfaro et al. 2004).

Table 4 Long-run AARDL estimation results

Broad money (M3) has a positive impact on economic growth. This result implies that the level of financial depth (the size and liquidity of the financial system) positively influences economic growth. A higher M3 level typically denotes stronger financial resource availability in an economy (Chao et al. 2021). Hence, a higher level of M3 leads to a lower interest rate and provides individuals and businesses with greater access to credit and financing, which, in turn, enables higher consumption and investment, ultimately boosting economic growth (Calderón and Liu 2003). There is evidence of similar findings in the empirical literature (e.g., Calderón and Liu 2003; Ogunmuyiwa and Ekone 2010).

The labor force has a negative but insignificant coefficient across specifications, implying no significant impact on economic growth (e.g., Rajab and Zouheir 2023). Although labor force growth is likely to positively impact economic growth, rapid population growth with inadequate institutional and economic infrastructure can strain resources and lead to rising unemployment. In addition, an abundant labor force may serve as a disincentive to technology adoption in an economy and hinder labor productivity from rising (Park-Poaps et al. 2021). Since Bangladesh economy is characterized by rapid population growth and abundant labor—a fact reflected by the low wage level and high unemployment rate—coupled with insufficient improvement in infrastructure, education, and skills, the labor force growth might have led to an inadequate increase in returns (labor productivity) and insignificant impacts on economic growth.

The coefficient of capital stock is positive and significant in all specifications, implying a positive impact on economic growth (e.g., Ramirez 2006). The result is as expected because the levels of domestic savings and capital stock are low in Bangladesh (i.e., it is a capital-deficient country); hence, an increase in capital stock immediately boosts productive capacity and output growth.

The global crises did not have any direct impact on economic growth, as the coefficients of the crises are insignificant in all specifications. This result implies that the economy managed to maintain economic growth by offsetting the direct impacts of external shocks. This result is tenable due to the following reasons: first, to some extent, the Bangladesh’s economy has moderately diversified industries, including garments and textiles, manufacturing, agriculture, and services, that help mitigate external shocks; second, Bangladesh’s home market is enormous with a sizable consumer base and massive domestic demand that acts as a buffer against external shocks; third, remittance inflows provide a stable sources of foreign exchange that supports household consumption; fourth, the shares of the agriculture and service sectors, whose productivity was not significantly negatively affected by external shocks, constitute a substantial portion of GDP, and these sectors play a crucial role in supporting livelihoods for a significant portion of the population.

Regarding the indirect impacts, the crises do not appear to have significantly affected the trade-growth relationship, as none of the coefficients of the interaction terms between crises and trade, crises and exports, or crises and imports are significant. Alternatively, the crises did not dampen trade-led growth, specifically, export-led growth. This was possible due to the structure of the Bangladeshi export basket. Readymade garments have been a significant part of Bangladeshi export earnings since the 1990s, and their contribution to total exports continues to increase. It has constituted more than 80% of Bangladeshi export earnings since the 2013–2014 fiscal year (BGMEA 2022). Surprisingly, the export earnings of the readymade garments sector were not distorted by any crisis considered in this study, which partly substantiates why no crisis had a distorting effect on trade-led growth in Bangladesh.

However, the coefficient of the interaction term between crises and FDI is negative and significant, implying that the crises dampened FDI-led growth in Bangladesh. In addition, the negative and significant value of the interaction term between crises and FDI outweighs the positive and significant value of the FDI coefficient, indicating that the crises distorted the positive effect of FDI on economic growth. Figure 1 shows visible crashes in the FDI inflow trend before 2010 (two crashes between 2005 and 2010), after 2016, and in 2020. These sudden crashes stemmed from the crises and the resulting slowdown in global economic activities (Joshua et al. 2020) despite Bangladesh’s efforts to maintain a fair level of FDI inflows. Although FDI inflows have been a source of GDP growth in Bangladesh, the sudden fall in FDI inflows in those years (Fig. 1) affected economic growth negatively. This substantiates, at least partly, why the crises distorted FDI-led growth in Bangladesh.

The results of the short-run dynamics with error correction are presented in Table 5. Both exports and imports exhibit similar short- and long-run effects. Specifically, the coefficient of exports for the current year in specification 1 is 0.077, which is significant at the 1% level, suggesting that a 1% increase in export earnings leads to an increase of 0.077% in real GDP. This relationship is noteworthy due to the considerable share of exports in Bangladesh’s GDP; thus, any sudden increase in exports will have an immediate impact on real GDP growth. FDI demonstrates a positive and significant impact on GDP growth in the short run as well like its long-run effect (as seen in specifications 3 and 7). FDI has played a pivotal role in driving economic growth in Bangladesh in recent decades (Ahamed and Tanin 2010; Khatun and Ahamad 2015; Rayhan 2014). Hence, an increase FDI inflows can immediately affect economic growth. As regards financial depth, M3 has a positive impact on economic growth in the short run and long run. Labor force, unlike its insignificant long-run effect, has a positive short-run effect, and capital, similar to its long-run impact, has a positive impact on economic growth in the short run.

Table 5 Short-run and ECM results

The crises do not exert any significant direct impact on economic growth in the short run (i.e., its coefficient is not significant in any specification). Additionally, none of the coefficients of the interaction terms of crises with trade variables (i.e., exports, imports, and total trade) are significant, implying that the crises had no short-run effect on trade-growth relationships. Nevertheless, the coefficient of the interaction term between crises and FDI is negative and significant, and its absolute value is more than the positive significant coefficient of FDI, which implies that the crises dampened FDI-led growth also in the short run. Finally, the coefficient of error correction (EC) is negative and significant with considerably high values in all specifications. This means that there is a quick adjustment toward long-run equilibrium relationships after a shock occurs in the short run.

As an additional diagnostic test of the stability of the models, this study presents plots of the cumulative sum (CUSUM) of recursive residuals and CUSUM of squares of recursive residuals in Figs. 2, 3, 4, 5, 6, 7, and 8 for specifications 1–7, respectively. All the plots (CUSUM and CUSUM of squares) across specifications reveal that the specified models and the estimated parameters are stable over the study period.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Plots of CUSUM and CUSUM of squares for specification 1

Fig. 3
figure 3

Plots of CUSUM and CUSUM of squares for specification 2

Fig. 4
figure 4

Plots of CUSUM and CUSUM of squares for specification 3

Fig. 5
figure 5

Plots of CUSUM and CUSUM of squares for specification 4

Fig. 6
figure 6

Plots of CUSUM and CUSUM of squares for specification 5

Fig. 7
figure 7

Plots of CUSUM and CUSUM of squares for specification 6

Fig. 8
figure 8

Plots of CUSUM and CUSUM of squares for specification 7

Robustness check

First, to check the robustness of the AARDL cointegration results, Bayer and Hanck (2013) cointegration is estimated, and the results are reported in Table 6. Both statistics—EG-JOH and EG-JOH-BO-BDM—are greater than the 5% significance values in all specifications, thereby implying that there are long-run cointegrating relationships among the variables.Footnote 12

Table 6 Bayer and Hanck cointegration test

Second, the FMOLS and DOLS methods are used to verify the robustness of the AARDL long-run results. Tables 7 and 8 report the results of FMOLS and DOLS, respectively. The results are similar to the AARDL long-run results that confirm the robustness of the long-run elasticities reported in Table 4.

Table 7 FMOLS estimation results
Table 8 DOLS estimation results

Conclusion and policy recommendations

A large number of studies have tested FDI- and trade-led growth hypotheses, with most concluding that both FDI and trade have positive and significant impacts on economic growth. However, few studies have investigated the effect of crises on economic growth through FDI and trade channels. Therefore, using time-series data on Bangladesh and the AARDL bounds testing approach, this study investigates whether three major crises (the 2007–2008 economic crisis, the 2016 commodity crisis, and the 2020 COVID-19 crisis) distorted FDI- and trade-led growth.

The results reveal that exports have positive effects and imports have insignificant effects on economic growth. Total trade (the sum of exports and imports) has a significant positive impact on economic growth only in the long run, whereas FDI has a positive and significant impact in both the short and long run. The crises are not found to have any direct effect on economic growth, either in the short run or long run. However, in terms of the indirect effects, the crises are found to have distorted the positive effect of FDI on economic growth (i.e., the crises distorted FDI-led growth) in both the short run and long run, while leaving trade-led growth unaffected.

These findings suggest that the economy of Bangladesh was insulated to some extent from external shocks transmitted through international trade channels but was unable to withstand them when they were transmitted through the FDI inflow channel. Readymade garments and textile industries, which account for a substantial part of total trade, contributed significantly to insulating the economy, at least partly, from global crises as these crises could not dampen the amount of Bangladesh’s export earnings remarkably. Although the COVID-19 crisis was both an internal and external shock and took a great toll on public health and subsequently on economic activities, major industries such as garments, textiles, and knitwear were not shut down for long in Bangladesh. Other industries, including those operating in the export processing zones, also continued production with little disruption, ensuring continuous exports and thus contributing to GDP. Overall, the structure of the economy (i.e., the share of agriculture, industry, and service sectors in GDP) and all the factors discussed in this study prevented any sharp decline in economic growth of Bangladesh during the crises. FDI inflows in Bangladesh, on the other hand, significantly declined following the major crises, including COVID-19, thus distorting the positive growth effect of FDI. The underlying reason is that global crises create uncertainty among foreign investors, thereby affecting global FDI flows particularly in emerging economies like Bangladesh.

Therefore, policymakers and business consultants should further emphasize the exploration of new international markets for garments and textile products to limit the effect of future crises on exports. This will significantly insulate the domestic economy from any external shocks. Additionally, the creation of a congenial investment climate and business atmosphere must also be prioritized to ensure continuous FDI inflows. Since the crises significantly reduced FDI inflows, specific fiscal measures, such as additional tax breaks and duty-free import and export, can be implemented in future. These measures can act as additional incentives for foreign investors on the one hand and reduce the extent of uncertainty ensuing from crises on the other. Specifically, measures should be positioned to escalate stimulus for economic growth and further liberalize the financial sector, if required. Attention should also be directed to developing human capital and formulating policies for a sound macroeconomic position to encourage foreign investment. Since this study dealt with a single developing country context, which is a limitation, the results cannot be generalized. Therefore, the research topic requires further investigation. Future studies should use data from several developing, developed, or mixed countries.

Availability of data and materials

FDI inflow data are taken from the UNCTAD database. The depreciation rate is sourced from the Penn World Table version 10.0. Data on other variables are drawn from the World Bank’s World Development Indicators (WDI) database.

Notes

  1. However, FDI inflows, in some cases, may exert a negative effect by crowding out domestic investment, causing dependence, and increasing external vulnerability (Aitken & Harrison 1999).

  2. Bangladesh economy, a major exporter of readymade garments and textile products, exports some manufactured products, including pharmaceutical, plastic, leather and textiles, and agricultural products (Export Promotion Bureau 2022). Bangladesh has been able to attract a large amount of FDI in the last two decades because of its adopted policies favoring foreign investment and also because it is an attractive destination for FDI due to its cheaper labor, increasing market size, and liberalized and investment-friendly economic environment, etc. (Dutta et al. 2017).

  3. The oil price shock of the 1990s (1990–1992) is not considered in this study because trade as a percentage of GDP in Bangladesh was insignificant in the 1990s (less than or around 20%). In addition, because of the low level of industrialization, energy consumption in Bangladesh was small compared with other LDCs, and energy imports as a percentage of energy use were also low (less than 20%) in the 1990s (World Bank 2021). The East Asian currency crisis of 1997–1998 had very little or no impact on Bangladesh economy because of the nature of the capital account and financial market in the country. Although the crisis scared many investors away from emerging markets in Asia, it could not affect Bangladesh as much given the fact that foreign financial assets and direct investment at that time were not substantial. Bangladesh also did not face the possibility of capital flight or a speculative attack on Taka due to the absence of any credible foreign exchange market. As the crisis evolved, foreign investment from South Korea and Taiwan in Bangladesh substantially declined, but overall FDI inflows continued to flourish (Chowdhury 1998). Hence, the East Asian currency crisis of 1997–98 is also not considered in this study.

  4. Liberal economists argue that international trade can lead nations to embrace more quickly contemporary technological change to enhance effective production (Jung & Marshall 1985; Kou et al. 2021).

  5. See Giles and Williams (2000), Krugman (1987), and McCombie and Thirlwall (1994) for surveys. This trade-growth relationship gained attention in the empirical literature, on the one hand, with the rapid economic growth achieved by newly industrialized Asian countries since the seventies and, on the other, with the Latin American import-substitution development strategy that simultaneously showed its limits and economic malfunction (Gómez et al. 2011).

  6. M3 is a measure of total money supply in an economy that includes M2 as well as large time deposits, institutional money market funds, short-term repurchase agreements, and other larger liquid assets.

  7. Pesaran et al. (2001) pointed out a “degenerate case” when the overall F-test and t-test on the lagged level of the dependent variable are statistically significant while the coefficients of the lagged levels of the independent variables are not different from zero. In this case, the significance of the F-test arises from the lagged level of the dependent variable, implying that the dependent variable is indeed stationary.

  8. Johansen (1995) developed a framework for modeling the data series of I(2). However, it is not applicable if any variable in a dataset has a different order of integration.

  9. This is done to ensure that there are no missing or extreme values in the dataset. The reason for using data from 1974 is to enhance the credibility of the results, as the use of potential lag lengths is likely to reduce the number of observations in the estimated results.

  10. Examples of industries that operate under the Special Bonded Warehouse Scheme include ready-made garments. It is a major contributor to the country’s export earnings.

  11. The value of the Durbin-Watson test statistic ranges from 0 to 4. A value of 2.0 means that there is no autocorrelation in the residuals. Its value between 0 and less than 2 implies positive autocorrelation, while a value between more than 2 and 4 implies negative autocorrelation.

  12. In this sentence, EG-JOH stands for Engle and Granger (1987)-Johansen (1988) test, and BO-BDM stands for Boswijk (1994)-Banerjee et al. (1998) test.

Abbreviations

AARDL:

Augmented autoregressive distributed lag

ADF:

Augmented Dickey Fuller

AIC:

Akaike info criterion

ARDL:

Autoregressive distributed lag

BEPZA:

Bangladesh export processing zone authority

BIDA:

Bangladesh investment development authority

COVID:

Coronavirus disease

CUSUM:

Cumulative sum

DF-GLS:

Dicky Fuller generalized least squares

DOLS:

Dynamic ordinary least squares

EC:

Error correction

EG–JOH:

Engle and Granger–Johansen

EG–JOH–BO–BDM:

Engle and Granger–Johansen–Boswijk–Banerjee Dolado and Mestre

EU:

European Union

FDI:

Foreign direct investment

FMOLS:

Fully modified ordinary least squares

GDP:

Gross domestic product

GFCF:

Gross fixed capital formation

IMF:

International Monetary Fund

KPSS:

Kwiatkowski–Phillips–Schmidt–Shin

KSS:

Kapetanios, Shin and Shell

LM:

Lagrange multiplier

R&D:

Research and Development

RESET:

Regression equation specification error test

UNCTAD:

United Nations Conference on Trade and Development

US$:

United State dollar

WDI:

World development indicators

References

Download references

Acknowledgements

I would like to thank Professor John Serieux for his valuable suggestions. I would also like to thank anonymous referees for their valuable comments and suggestions that improved the quality of this paper.

Funding

This research did not receive any specific grants from funding agencies in the public, commercial, or not-for-profit sectors.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

BS is responsible for all the work done in this research article.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Bibhuti Sarker.

Ethics declarations

Competing interests

The author declares that he has no competing interests.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

See Table 9.

Table 9 Definition of variables

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article's Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article's Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Sarker, B. FDI-growth and trade-growth relationships during crises: evidence from Bangladesh. Financ Innov 10, 55 (2024). https://doi.org/10.1186/s40854-023-00571-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1186/s40854-023-00571-6

Keywords

JEL Classification