Skip to main content
Log in

Re-contracting intergovernmental organizations: Membership change and the creation of linked intergovernmental organizations

  • SI: The Power of the Weak
  • Published:
The Review of International Organizations Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

How do intergovernmental organizations (IGOs) evolve? Cooperation through IGOs is difficult to maintain, as membership dynamics change dramatically over time, leading to dissatisfaction with the status quo. This paper argues that IGO members states create new affiliated bodies, which I call linked intergovernmental organizations (LIGOs), to “re-contract” their cooperation. This helps IGOs adapt to changing membership dynamics, including the addition of new members and shifting constellations of power and preference. LIGOs are particularly useful for weak or formerly weak states seeking to alter the institutional status quo. Several features of LIGOs incentivize their creation: (1) they bypass difficult-to-enact reforms at existing IGOs; (2) flexible design features increase the voice of dissatisfied constituencies; and (3) they are politically viable for dissatisfied and status quo members of IGOs. To test my argument, I analyze original data on 1,200 LIGOs created between 1945 and 2012. Multivariate statistical analyses show that LIGOs are created in response to shifting membership environments that create demands for change at existing IGOs. I complement the quantitative analysis with case studies of two significant LIGOs: The International Development Agency (IDA) and United Nations Environment Programme (UNEP). My theory suggests a dramatic rethinking of how international cooperation evolves and has broad implications for global governance in an increasingly multipolar world.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Data availability

All data generated and analyzed during this study are included in the Supplementary files.

Notes

  1. Aside from several well-known examples, such as the UK withdraw from the EU, exit is rare. According to von Borzyskowki and Vabulas, withdraw happens in about 0.04% of IGO-member-years, which they note means that “most states actually remain in the IGOs they join and withdraw rarely” (2019, p. 339). Moreover, work on the death of IGOs finds that few major IGOs have died in the post 1945 era (Gray, 2018; Eilstrup-Sangiovanni, 2020).

  2. There exists considerable variation in LIGO design. In some cases, member states or territories who are not members of the IGO are allowed to have a voice in the LIGO. In other cases, states must opt-in via another procedure such as the signature of a separate treaty or accession document.

  3. “Emanations” as a category seems to have originated as one of the 15 categories of intergovernmental organization used by the yearbook of international organizations (YIO), but actual usage seems to vary.

  4. UN System expenditures broken down by agency: https://unsceb.org/fs-revenue-agency.

  5. Many datasets on IGOs that claim to exclude LIGO-like entities nevertheless include organizations such as IDA which shares the same staff and governing body as the IBRD.

  6. Veto power over amendments to the UN Charter is specified in Articles 108 and 109. At founding, amendments to the IBRD and IMF’s Articles of Agreement required 80% of the total vote of the board of governors, giving the US effective veto power. Both were subsequently amended, at the behest of the US, when the US vote share dropped below 20%. Now amendments require 85%.

  7. The WTO requires that amendment proposals be reached by consensus and then, depending on the article/section, requires either a 2/3 or 3/4 vote to approve.

  8. UN members regularly call conferences on specific topics, which can be used to establish a LIGO directly via treaty, or they can use them to negotiate the terms of a LIGO which they then present to another body, often the General Assembly, for a vote.

  9. https://news.naver.com/main/read.nhn?mode=LSD&mid=sec&sid1=101&oid=001&aid=0004229565.

  10. Research suggests that IGO membership can take up a large portion of countries’ foreign affairs budgets (See Gray, 2018). Moreover, studies show that negotiations for new institutions can take years (Lechner & Wüthrich, 2018). Finally, headquarters buildings and other infrastructure costs are often immense. The new IRENA headquarters reportedly cost over $200 million, and recently China has financed millions of dollars for the building of IGO buildings in Africa such as the new ECOWAS headquarters, which cost over $30 million, and the AU headquarters which cost $200 million. https://www.cfr.org/blog/china-build-new-ecowas-headquarters-abuja.

  11. The COW 3.0 data includes several IGOs that I categorized as LIGOs; I discard these as well as IGOs that die before 1945.

  12. Approximately 982 LIGOs have a first order connection. This correspondence is not 100% for two reasons: (1) some LIGOs have a primary linkage to an IGO that is not included in the COW IGO, (2) some LIGOs start as IGOs but become linked at a later date.

  13. The distinction between what I call first order and second order LIGOs is discussed in the Appendix.

  14. HHI indices are commonly used to indicate how concentrated market power is in industries. Formally, an HHI index is defined as \(H=\sum\nolimits_{i=1}^{N}{s}_{i}^{2}\), where \({s}_{i}\) is the market share and N is the number of firms. In the current case, \({s}_{i}\) is the power share of the country (or GDP, population, or military expenditure share) in each IGO and N is the number of members in the IGO.

  15. To confirm I ran an auxiliary regression to test the null hypothesis that V[yi|xi] = E[yi|xi] versus the alternative that V[yi|xi] = E[yi|xi] + alpha(E[yi|xi])^2. The p-value was 0.000. Additionally, a likelihood ratio test of alpha = 0 is statistically significant at conventional levels.

  16. See Carter and Signorino (2010).

  17. This is effectively a subset of larger, more important IGOs, which suggests that the findings are not driven solely by unique features of less consequential IGOs.

  18. Original proposals by the US and UK called for 32 states. Additionally, the General Assembly dismantled the Governing Council in favor of a new “United Nations Environment Assembly (UNEA)” with universal participation by all members (see DeSombre, 2017 p. 11).

References

  • Abbott, K. W., & Faude, B. (2022). The Review of International Organizations, 17(2), 263–291.

  • Abbott, K. W., & Snidal, D. (1998). Why states act through formal international organizations. Journal of conflict resolution, 42(1), 3–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Abbott, K. W., Genschel, P., Snidal, D., & Zangl, B. (2015). International organizations as orchestrators. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Abbott, K. W., Green, J. F., & Keohane, R. O. (2016). International Organization, 70(2), 247–277.

  • Acharya, A. (2017). After liberal hegemony: The advent of a multiplex world order. Ethics & International Affairs, 31(3), 271–285.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aggarwal, V. K. (Ed.). (1998). Institutional designs for a complex world: Bargaining, linkages, and nesting. Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alter, K. J., & Meunier, S. (2009). The politics of international regime complexity. Perspectives on Politics, 7, 13–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alter, K. J., & Raustiala, K. (2018). The rise of international regime complexity. Annual Review of Law and Social Science, 14, 329–349.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alvarez, J. E. (2005). International organizations as law-makers. Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Andresen, S. (2001). Global environmental governance: UN fragmentation and co-ordination. Yearbook of International co-operation on Environment and Development, 2002, 19–26.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bailey, M. A., Strezhnev, A., & Voeten, E. (2017). Estimating dynamic state preferences from United Nations voting data. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 61(2), 430–456.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barnett, M., & Finnemore, M. (2004). Rules for the World: International organizations in Global politics. Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beall, K. Empowering to constrain: Procedural checks and constraint through delegation. Review of International Organizations. This issue.

  • Benjamin, B. (2007). Uncomfortable intimacies: Managing third world nationalisms. In Invested Interests: Capital, Culture and the World Bank (pp. 55-89). Minneapolis; London: University of Minnesota Press.

  • Busch, M. L. (2007). Overlapping institutions, forum shopping, and dispute settlement in international trade. International Organization, 61, 735–761.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chan, G. (1992). Japan and the World Bank from burden-sharing to power-sharing. Japanese Studies, 12(3), 2–18.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, R. (2021). Pool or duel? Cooperation and competition among international organizations. International Organization, 75(4), 1133–1153.

    Article  ADS  Google Scholar 

  • Carter, D. B., & Signorino, C. S. (2010). Back to the future: Modeling time dependence in binary data. Political Analysis, 18(3), 271–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chorev, N. (2017). The World Health Organization between north and south. Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cooley, A., & Nexon, D. H. (2020). How hegemony ends. Foreign Affairs, 99, 143.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cox, R. W., & Jacobson, H. K. (1973). The anatomy of influence; decision making in international organization. Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dallin, A. (1962). The Soviet View of the United Nations. International Organization, 16(1), 20–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Debre, M. J., & Dijkstra, H. (2021). Institutional design for a post-liberal order: why some international organizations live longer than others. European Journal of International Relations, 27(1), 311–339.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DeSombre, E. R. (2017). Global environmental institutions. Taylor and Francis.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Eilstrup-Sangiovanni, M. (2020). Death of international organizations. The organizational ecology of intergovernmental organizations, 1815–2015. The Review of International Organizations, 15(2), 339–370.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eilstrup-Sangiovanni, M., & Westerwinter, O. (2022). The global governance complexity cube: Varieties of institutional complexity in global governance. The Review of International Organizations, 17(2), 233–262.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fioretos, O. (Ed.). (2017). International politics and institutions in time. Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fioretos, O. (2011). Historical institutionalism in international relations. International Organization, 65, 367–399.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freeman, J., Carroll, G. R., & Hannan, M. T. (1983). The liability of newness: Age dependence in organizational death rates. American Sociological Review, 48, 692–710.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedmann, B. W. (1957, Nov 03). Memo on helping 'have-not' nations: More business like assistance programs are called for, without political strings. Memo on helping 'have-not' nations. New York Times (1923-Current File) Retrieved from https://search.proquest.com/docview/114312405?accountid=14696

  • Gehring, T., & Faude, B. (2014). A theory of emerging order within institutional complexes: How competition among regulatory international institutions leads to institutional adaptation and division of labor. The Review of International Organizations, 9(4), 471–498.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilpin, R. (1981). War and change in world politics. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Graham, E. R., & Serdaru, A. (2020). Power, control, and the logic of substitution in institutional design: The case of International Climate Finance. International Organization, 74(4), 671–706.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gray, J. (2018). Life, death, or zombie? The vitality of international organizations. International Studies Quarterly, 62(1), 1–13.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gruber, L. (2000). Ruling the world: Power politics and the rise of supranational institutions. Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Gutner, T., & Thompson, A. (2010). The politics of IO performance: A framework. The Review of International Organizations, 5(3), 227–248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haas, E. B. (1958). The uniting of Europe: Political, social, and economic forces, 1950–1957. Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haftel, Y. Z., & Lenz, T. (2022). Measuring institutional overlap in global governance. The Review of International Organizations, 17, 323–347.

  • Hale, T., Held, D., & Young, K. (2013). Gridlock: Why global cooperation is failing when we need it most. Polity.

  • Hanrieder, T. (2015). The path-dependent design of international organizations: Federalism in the World Health Organization. European Journal of International Relations, 21(1), 215–239.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heldt, E., & Schmidtke, H. (2017). Measuring the empowerment of international organizations: The evolution of financial and staff capabilities. Global Policy, 8, 51–61.

    Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  • Helfer, L. R. (2004). Regime shifting: The TRIPs agreement and new dynamics of international intellectual property lawmaking. Yale J Int’l L, 29, 1.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hooghe, L., Lenz, T., & Marks, G. (2019). A theory of international organization. Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hooghe, L., & Marks, G. (2015). Delegation and pooling in international organizations. The Review of International Organizations, 10(3), 305–328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ikenberry, G. J. (2001). After victory: Institutions, Strategic Restraint, and the rebuilding of Order after Major Wars. Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ikenberry, G. J. (2017). The rise, character, and evolution of international order. In O. Fioretos (Ed.), International politics and institutions in time. Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ikenberry, G. J., & Nexon, D. H. (2019). Hegemony studies 3.0: The dynamics of Hegemonic orders. Security Studies, 28(3), 395–421.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ivanova, Maria (2007). Moving forward by looking back: Learning from UNEP's history. In: Lydia and Estelle Perry (eds) Global Environmental Governance: Perspectives on the Current Debate. Center for UN Reform Education (pp. 26-47). New York

  • Ivanova, M. (2010). UNEP in global environmental governance: design, leadership, location. Global Environmental Politics, 10(1), 30–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jervis, R. (1976). Perception and misperception in international politics: New Edition. Princeton University Press.

  • Johnson, S. (2012). UNEP the first 40 years. UNEP.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, T. (2014). Organizational progeny: Why governments are losing control over the proliferating structures of global governance. Oxford University Press.

  • Jupille, J., Mattli, W., & Snidal, D. (2013). Institutional choice and Global Commerce. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kahler, M. (2013). Rising powers and global governance: negotiating change in a resilient status quo. International affairs, 89(3), 711–729.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kapur, D., Lewis, J. P., & Webb, R. C. (2011). The World Bank: its first half century (Vol. 1). Brookings Institution Press.

  • Kastner, S. L., Pearson, M. M., & Rector, C. (2016). Invest, hold up, or accept? China in multilateral governance. Security Studies, 25(1), 142–179.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kastner, S. L., Pearson, M. M., & Rector, C. (2018). China's strategic multilateralism: Investing in global governance. Cambridge University Press.

  • Keohane, R. O. (1984). After hegemony: Cooperation and discord in the world political economy. Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keohane, R. O., & Ostrom, E. (Eds.). (1994). Local commons and global interdependence. Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Koremenos, B. (2016). The continent of international law: Explaining agreement design. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Koremenos, B., Lipson, C., & Snidal, D. (2001). The rational design of international institutions. International organization, 55(4), 761–799.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krasner, S. D. (1976). State power and the structure of international trade. World politics, 28(3), 317–347.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krasner, S. D. (1985). Structural conflict: The third world against global liberalism (Vol. 12). Univ of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krasner, S. D. (1991). Global communications and national power: Life on the Pareto frontier. World politics, 43(3), 336–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kruck, A., & Zangl, B. (2020). The adjustment of international institutions to global power shifts: A framework for analysis. Global Policy, 11, 5–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lake, D. A., Martin, L. L., & Risse, T. (2021). Challenges to the liberal order: Reflections on international organization. International organization, 75(2), 225–257.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lall, R. (2017). Beyond institutional design: Explaining the performance of international organizations. International Organization, 71, 245–280.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lechner, L., & Wüthrich, S. (2018). Seal the deal: Bargaining positions, Institutional Design, and the duration of Preferential Trade negotiations. International Interactions, 44(5), 833–861.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lipscy, P. Y. (2017). Renegotiating the world order: Institutional change in international relations. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Littoz-Monnet, A. (2017). Expert knowledge as a strategic resource: International bureaucrats and the shaping of bioethical standards. International Studies Quarterly, 61(3), 584–595.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Manulak, M. The sources of influence in multilateral diplomacy: Replaceability and intergovermental networks in international institutions. Review of International Organizations. This issue.

  • Manulak, M. W. (2017). Leading by design: Informal influence and international secretariats. The Review of International Organizations, 12(4), 497–522.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • March, J. G., & Olsen, J. P. (1998). The institutional dynamics of international political orders. International Organization, 52, 943–969.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mason, E. S., & Asher, R. E. (1973). The world bank since Bretton Woods. Brookings Institution Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mearsheimer, J. J. (2019). Bound to fail: The rise and fall of the liberal international order. International security, 43(4), 7–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mesquita, R. The only living guerrillero in New York: Cuba and the brokerage power of a resilient revisionist state. Review of International Organizations. This issue. 

  • Milewicz, K. M., & Elsig, M. (2014). The hidden world of multilateralism: Treaty commitments of newly democratized states in Europe. International Studies Quarterly, 58(2), 322–335.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morse, J., Coggins, B. Your silence speaks volumes: The politics of absence in the UN General Assembly. Review of International Organizations. This issue.

  • Morse, J. C., & Keohane, R. O. (2014). Contested multilateralism. The Review of International Organizations, 9(4), 385–412.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Musgrave, P., & Nexon, D. H. (2018). Defending hierarchy from the moon to the Indian Ocean: Symbolic capital and political dominance in early modern China and the cold war. International Organization, 72(3), 591–626.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Najam, A. (2005). Developing countries and global environmental governance: From contestation to participation to engagement. International Environmental Agreements: Politics Law and Economics, 5(3), 303–321.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nye, J. S. (1974). UNCTAD: Poor Nations’ Pressure Group. In Cox & Jacobson. The Anatomy of Influence: Decision Making in International Organisations, pp. 334–370.

  • Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action; public goods and the theory of groups. Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pevehouse, J. C., Nordstrom, T., McManus, R. W., & Jamison, A. S. (2020). Tracking organizations in the world: The correlates of War IGO Version 3.0 datasets. Journal of Peace Research, 57(3), 492–503.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pincus, J. A., & Council on Foreign Relations. (1967). Trade, aid, and development: the rich and poor nations. [1st ed.] New York: Published for the Council on Foreign Relations by McGraw-Hill.

  • Poast, P., & Urpelainen, J. (2013). Fit and feasible: Why democratizing states form, not join, international organizations. International Studies Quarterly, 57(4), 831–841.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pratt, T. (2018). Deference and hierarchy in international regime complexes. International Organization, 72(3), 561–590.

    Article  ADS  Google Scholar 

  • Pratt, T. (2021). Angling for influence: Institutional proliferation in development banking. International Studies Quarterly, 65(1), 95–108.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reed, W. (2003). Information, power, and war. American Political Science Review, 97(4), 633–641.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reinsberg, B., & Westerwinter, O. (2023). Institutional overlap in global governance and the design of intergovernmental organizations. The Review of International Organizations18, 693–724.

  • Renshon, J. (2017). Fighting for status: Hierarchy and conflict in world politics. Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Raustiala, K., & Victor, D. G. (2004). The regime complex for plant genetic resources. International organization, 58(2), 277–309.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roger, C. B., & Rowan, S. S. (2022). Analyzing international organizations: How the concepts we use affect the answers we get. The Review of International Organizations, 17(3), 597–625.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shanks, C., Jacobson, H. K., & Kaplan, J. H. (1996). Inertia and change in the constellation of international governmental organizations, 1981–1992. International Organization, 50, 593–627.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Snidal, D., Hale, T., Jones, E., Mertens, C., & Milewicz, K., The power of the “weak” and international organizations. Review of International Organizations. This issue.

  • Steil, B. (2013). The battle of Bretton Woods: John Maynard Keynes, Harry Dexter White, and the making of a new world order. Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Stephen, M. D., & Parízek, M. (2019). New powers and the distribution of preferences in global trade governance: From deadlock and drift to fragmentation. New Political Economy, 24(6), 735–758.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stone, R. W. (2011). Controlling institutions: International organizations and the global economy. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Thies, C. G., & Nieman, M. D. (2017). Rising powers and foreign policy revisionism: Understanding BRICS identity and behavior through time. University of Michigan Press.

  • Toye, J., & Toye, R. (2004). The Un and global political economy: Trade, finance, and development. Indiana University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vabulas, F., & Snidal, D. (2013). Organization without delegation: Informal intergovernmental organizations (IIGOs) and the spectrum of intergovernmental arrangements. The Review of International Organizations, 8(2), 193–220.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vabulas, F., & Snidal, D. (2021). Cooperation under autonomy: Building and analyzing the Informal Intergovernmental Organizations 2.0 dataset. Journal of Peace Research, 58(4), 859–869.

  • Vaubel, R., Dreher, A., & Soylu, U. (2007). Staff growth in international organizations: A principal-agent problem? An empirical analysis. Public Choice, 133(3–4), 275–295.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Voeten, E. (2001). Outside options and the logic of Security Council action. American Political Science Review, 95, 845–858.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Voeten, E. (2021). Ideology and international institutions. Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Von Borzyskowski, I., & Vabulas, F. (2019). Hello, goodbye: When do states withdraw from international organizations? The Review of International Organizations, 14(2), 335–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Walter, S. (2021). The backlash against globalization. Annual Review of Political Science, 24, 421–442.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weaver, J. H. (1965). The International Development Association: a new approach to foreign aid. New York: Praeger.

    Google Scholar 

  • White, N. (2016). Lawmaking. In J. K. Cogan, I. Hurd, & I. Johnstone (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of international organizations. Oxford University Press.

  • Wood, S. (2013). Prestige in world politics: History, theory, expression. International Politics, 50(3), 387–411.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zelli, F., & Van Asselt, H. (2013). Introduction: The institutional fragmentation of global environmental governance: Causes, consequences, and responses. Global Environmental Politics, 13(3), 1–13.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zürn, M. (2018). A theory of global governance: Authority, legitimacy, and contestation. Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

Many people helped in the development of this project. I would like to give a special thanks to Todd Allee, Scott Kastner, Jennifer Hadden, Virginia Haufler, Duncan Snidal, Thomas Hale, Julia Morse, Manfred Elsig, Bernhard Reinsberg, and Sam Rowan, as well as editors and reviewers at The Review of International Organizations. I also owe a special thanks to many participants at the 2022 Political Economy of International Organizations conference and the 2021 International Studies Association Meeting. All errors are my own.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Andrew Lugg.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The author has no relevant financial or non-financial interests to disclose.

Additional information

Responsible editors: Claas Mertens & Duncan Snidal

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Supplementary information

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

ESM 1

(DOCX 59.2 KB)

ESM 2

(ZIP 1.69 MB)

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Lugg, A. Re-contracting intergovernmental organizations: Membership change and the creation of linked intergovernmental organizations. Rev Int Organ (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-024-09533-8

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-024-09533-8

Keywords

Navigation