Skip to main content
Log in

Prevention externalities: private and public responses to the 1878 yellow fever epidemic

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Standard economic theory suggests that government is a cheaper way to internalize prevention externalities than private entities. This paper argues that this view depends on unexamined assumptions about transaction costs and the costs of improving state capacity. Public and private entities might be cheaper ways to internalize prevention externalities depending on differences in transaction costs, state capacity, and the willingness to improve public health. The 1878 yellow fever epidemic throughout the lower Mississippi Valley—one of the worst epidemiological disasters in the United States during the nineteenth century—provides ample context to examine this argument. Primary responses include municipal quarantine, flight from towns and cities, and the formation of refugee camps. Whereas municipal governments cheaply provided some quarantine services, individuals and private actors cheaply fled from infected areas and governed refugee camps. Responses in Memphis, one of the worst affected areas, further demonstrate that differences in these costs influence prevention externalities and how public and private entities respond to complex disease problems.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Echoing Hume and other classic political economists, Mueller (2003) notes that public goods problems form a core justification of state formation.

  2. For a critique of this literature, see Coyne, Duncan, and Hall (2021).

  3. For more on the transaction costs associated with sexually transmitted diseases and social norms, see Lloyd (1991), Parish (1992), Lloyd (1992), and Carson (2017).

  4. On distance from vectors as a means of prevention, similar marginal responses take place prior to natural disasters and public health crises (Agüero and Beleche 2017; Carson 2022; Gutmann and Field 2010; Philipson and Posner 1993).

  5. Price (2016) refers mostly to quarantines of the 1880s and 1890s.

  6. On the efficacy of migration as a means of prevention, especially when people are certain about their health status, see Mesnard and Seabright (2009, 2016).

  7. People have myriad subjective values, which is difficult knowledge for planners to access (Boettke and Powell 2021).

  8. There were also about 1000 refugees in a camp outside of Grenada, MS (Power 1879; Winston 2020).

  9. I thank a reviewer for pointing out that quick population losses entail additional costs and negative selection effects. Many people who stayed in the city could have avoided yellow fever if they had coordinated with those who fled (prior to their departure) or if they had formed additional camps.

  10. Regarding Camp Joe Williams, discussed below, Dr. Nall states, “The camp was inhabited by the lower classes, and from the districts where the plague was most violent” (Keating 1879, p. 395).

  11. Keating (1879, p. 394) lists the regulations for Joe Williams, which range from a daily schedule to policing and airing out one's tent and from obligations regarding police duty to punishment for violations.

  12. The minutes of the board of health from 1878, edited by Hicks (1964, p. 1), indicate that “[t]he first regular meeting of the Board of Health was held…on March 11th 1878,” and that the board comprised three physicians, the mayor, and the chief of police.

  13. I thank a reviewer for pointing out this issue, which encouraged me to think more critically about the case and to look for additional details.

  14. I thank a reviewer for making the connection to civil war POW camps.

References

  • Agüero, J. M., & Beleche, T. (2017). Health shocks and their long-lasting impact on health behaviors: Evidence from the 2009 H1N1 pandemic in Mexico. Journal of Health Economics, 54, 40–55.

    Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  • Albrecht, B. C., & Rajagopalan, S. (2023). Inframarginal externalities: COVID-19, vaccines, and universal mandates. Public Choice, 195, 55–72.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Annual Report of the National Board of Health. (1879). 1879. U.S. Government Printing Office.

  • Annual Report of the National Board of Health. (1880). 1881. U.S. Government Printing Office.

  • Anomaly, J. (2011). Public health and public goods. Public Health Ethics, 4(3), 251–259.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anomaly, J. (2021). What is public health? Public goods, publicized goods, and the conversion problem. Public Choice, 195, 43–53.

    PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  • Augustin, G. (1909). History of Yellow Fever. New Orleans. https://archive.org/details/historyofyellowf00auguuoft/page/n3/mode/2up

  • Barzel, Y. (1997). Economic Analysis of Property Rights. 2nd ed. Political Economy of Institutions and Decisions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

  • Bleakley, H., Cain, L. P., & Hong, S. C. (2018). Health, disease, and sanitation in American economic history. The Oxford Handbook of American Economic History, Vol. 1.

  • Boettke, P., & Powell, B. (2021). The political economy of the COVID-19 pandemic. Southern Economic Journal, 87(4), 1090–1106.

    Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  • Bogart, D., Dunn, O. B., Alvarez-Palau, E. J., & Shaw-Taylor, L. (2022). Organizations and efficiency in public services: The case of English lighthouses revisited. Economic Inquiry, 60(2), 975–994.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bohn, L. (1996). ‘An oasis in a desert of woe’: The Yellow Fever epidemic in Jackson, Madison county, Tennessee. The West Tennessee Historical Society Papers, 50, 105–114.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowditch, H. I., & Pickering, H. G. (1877). Public Hygiene in America: Being the Centennial Discourse Delivered Before the International Medical Congress, Philadelphia, September, 1876. Little, Brown.

  • Brady, J. (1986). The Irish community in antebellum Memphis. The West Tennessee Historical Society Papers, 40, 24–44.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bridges, W. H. (1867). Digest of the Charters and Ordinances of the City of Memphis, from 1826 to 1867, Inclusive: Together with the Acts of the Legislature Relating to the City, with an Appendix. Bulletin Publishing Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brieba, D. (2018). State capacity and health outcomes: Comparing Argentina’s and Chile’s reduction of infant and maternal mortality, 1960–2013. World Development, 101, 37–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bristow, E. (1967). From temple to barn: The Greenlaw Opera House in Memphis 1860–1880. The West Tennessee Historical Society Papers, 21, 5–23.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bruesch, S. R. (1952). The disasters and epidemics of a river town: Memphis, Tennessee, 1819–1879. Bulletin of the Medical Library Association, 40(3), 288–305.

    CAS  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent: logical foundations of constitutional democracy. Liberty Fund.

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1965). An economic theory of clubs. Economica, 32(125), 1–14.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Stubblebine, W. C. (1962). Externality. Economica, 29(116), 371–384.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burdekin, R. C. K., and P. L. Siklos. 2013. Gold resumption and the deflation of the 1870s. In Routledge handbook of major events in economic history. Routledge.

  • Callais, J. T., & Geloso, V. (2023). The political economy of lighthouses in antebellum America. European Economic Review, 154, 104425. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.euroecorev.2023.104425

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Candela, R. A., & Geloso, V. (2018). The lightship in economics. Public Choice, 176(3), 479–506.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Candela, R. A., & Geloso, V. (2019). Coase and transaction costs reconsidered: The case of the English lighthouse system. European Journal of Law and Economics, 48(3), 331–349.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Candela, R. A., & Geloso, V. (2021). Economic freedom, pandemics, and robust political economy. Southern Economic Journal, 87(4), 1250–1266.

    Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  • Capers, G. M. (1938). Yellow Fever in Memphis in the 1870s. The Mississippi Valley Historical Review, 24(4), 483–502. https://doi.org/10.2307/1947043

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carden, A., & Keeling, S. (2011). Recovery after disasters: New Orleans, Paris, and Memphis. Studies in Emergent Order, 4, 31–39.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carson, B. (2016). Firm-Led Malaria prevention in the United States, 1910–1920. American Journal of Law & Medicine, 42(2–3), 310–332.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carson, B. (2017). The informal norms of HIV prevention: The emergence and erosion of the Condom Code. The Journal of Law, Medicine & Ethics, 45(4), 518–530.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carson, B. (2020). Privately preventing Malaria in the United States, 1900–1925. Essays in Economic & Business History, 38(1), 142–192.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carson, B. (2021). Automatons or individuals? Voluntary responses to COVID-19 related epidemic externalities. The Independent Review, 25(4), 551.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carson, B. (2022). Individuals and externalities in economic epidemiology: A tension and synthesis. Journal of Private Enterprise, 37(3), 1–24.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carson, B. (2023). Challenging Malaria: The private and social incentives of mosquito control. Palgrave Macmillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Carson, B., Isaacs, J., & Carilli, T. (2022). Jabbing together? The complementarity between social capital, formal public health rules, and COVID-19 vaccine rates in the United States. Vaccine, 40(27), 3781–3787.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  • Cheung, S. (1973). The fable of the bees: An economic investigation. The Journal of Law & Economics, 16(1), 11–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clotfelter, C. (1973). Memphis business leadership and the politics of fiscal crisis. The West Tennessee Historical Society Papers, 27, 33–49.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (1937). The nature of the firm. Economica, 4(16), 386–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (1960). The problem of social cost. The Journal of Law & Economics, 3, 1–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (1974). The lighthouse in economics. The Journal of Law & Economics, 17(2), 357–376.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cornes, R., & Sandler, T. (1996). The theory of externalities, public goods, and club goods (2nd ed.). Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Cowen, N., & Schliesser, E. (2023). Novel externalities. Public Choice. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-023-01072-x

    Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  • Cowen, T. (1985). Public goods definitions and their institutional context: A critique of public goods theory. Review of Social Economy, 43(1), 53–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coyne, C. J., Duncan, T. K., & Hall, A. R. (2021). The political economy of state responses to Infectious disease. Southern Economic Journal, 87(4), 1119–1137.

    Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  • Deming, D. (2020). The aqueducts and water supply of Ancient Rome. Ground Water, 58(1), 152–161.

    Article  MathSciNet  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Ellis, J. H. (1974). Disease and the destiny of a city: The 1878 Yellow Fever epidemic in Memphis. West Tennessee Historical Society Papers, 28, 75–89.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ellis, J. H. (1992). Yellow Fever and public health in the new south. University Press of Kentucky.

    Google Scholar 

  • Furton, G. L. (2023). The pox of politics: Troesken’s tradeoff reexamined. Public Choice, 195(1), 169–191.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Geloso, V. (2021). Conceptualizing the cost of COVID policy: The role of institutional trade-offs. The Economists’ Voice, 18(1), 129–136.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geloso, V., & Bologna Pavlik, J. (2021). Economic freedom and the economic consequences of the 1918 pandemic. Contemporary Economic Policy, 39(2), 255–263.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geloso, V., Hyde, K., & Murtazashvili, I. (2021). Pandemics, economic freedom, and institutional trade-offs. European Journal of Law and Economics, 54, 37–61.

    Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  • Geoffard, P., & Philipson, T. (1996). Rational epidemics and their public control. International Economic Review, 37(3), 603–624.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gersovitz, M. (2000). A preface to the economic analysis of disease transmission. Australian Economic Papers, 39(1), 68–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gersovitz, M., & Hammer, J. S. (2004). The economical control of infectious diseases. The Economic Journal, 114(492), 1–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gersovitz, M., & Hammer, J. S. (2005). Tax/Subsidy policies toward vector-borne infectious diseases. Journal of Public Economics, 89(4), 647–674.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Getz, J. (1991). St. Brigid’s church: The first decade of an Irish parish in Memphis, 1870–79. West Tennessee Historical Society Papers, 45, 153–159.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gutmann, M. P., & Field, V. (2010). Katrina in historical context: Environment and migration in the U.S. Population and Environment, 31(1–3), 3–19.

  • Harris, E. (1875). Report on the public health service in the principal cities, and sanitary works in the United States. Public Health Papers and Reports, 2, 151–186.

    CAS  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, M. (1964). “Yellow Fever and the Board of Health, Memphis, 1878.” Memphis, TN: The Memphis and Shelby County Health Department. Box 1, File 6, Item 2, Yellow Fever Collection. Memphis and Shelby County Room, Memphis Public Library.

  • Institute of Medicine. (1988). Summary of the public health system in the United States. Committee for the Study of the Future of Public. In The Future of Public Health. National Academies Press (US). https://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/books/NBK218212/.

  • Keating, J. M. (1879). A history of the Yellow Fever: The Yellow Fever epidemic of 1878, in Memphis, Tenn., embracing a complete list of the dead, the names of the doctors and nurses employed, names of all who contributed money or means, and the names and history of the Howards, together with ther data, and lists of the dead elsewhere. Howard Association.

  • Keating, J. M., & Vedder, O. F. (1888). History of the city of Memphis and Shelby county, Tennessee, with illustrations and biographical sketches of some of Its prominent citizens. Syracuse, N.Y.: D. Mason & Co. https://catalog.hathitrust.org/Record/100734509.

  • Kennedy, S. W., Curtis, A. J., & Curtis, J. W. (2015). Historic disease data as epidemiological resource: Searching for the origin and local basic reproduction number of the 1878 Yellow Fever epidemic in Memphis, Tennessee. Annals of the Association of American Geographers, 105(5), 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klein, D. (1987). Tie-ins and the market provision of collective goods. Harvard Journal of Law & Public Policy, 10, 451.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klein, D. (1990). The voluntary provision of public goods? The turnpike companies of early America. Economic Inquiry, 28(4), 788–812.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lanier, R. (2012). The Memphis legal community under federal occupation, 1860–1870. The West Tennessee Historical Society Papers, 66, 27–64.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T., & Rouanet, L. (2021). Externality and COVID-19. Southern Economic Journal, 87(4), 1107–1118.

    Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T., & Thompson, H. A. (2021). Public choice and public health. Public Choice, 195, 5–41.

    Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  • Legler, J. B., Sylla, R., & Wallis, J. J. (1988). U.S. city finances and the growth of government, 1850–1902. The Journal of Economic History, 48(2), 347–356.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lloyd, P. J. (1991). Aids: An economic approach to the choice of policies. Economic Record, 67(2), 126–138.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lloyd, P. J. (1992). Aids and ‘Market Failure’; a reply. Economic Record, 68(3), 281–282.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mallory, J. B. (1874). Account of the Yellow Fever epidemic in Memphis, Tennessee, in 1873. American Journal of Medical Sciences, 67, 343–359.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maltsev, V. V. (2023). Decentralized response as a pandemic second-best: The case of Russia. Southern Economic Journal. https://doi.org/10.1002/soej.12653

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mesnard, A., & Seabright, P. (2009). Escaping epidemics through migration? Quarantine measures under incomplete information about infection risk. Journal of Public Economics, 93(7), 931–938.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mesnard, A., & Seabright, P. (2016). Migration and the equilibrium prevalence of infectious diseases. Journal of Demographic Economics, 82(1), 1–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D. C. (2003). Public choice III. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Mulligan, C. B. (2023). Beyond Pigou: externalities and civil society in the supply–demand framework. Public Choice, 196, 1–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Munger, M. C. (2018). Tomorrow 3.0: Transaction costs and the sharing economy. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Murtazashvili, I., & Zhou, Y. (2023). Complex externalities, pandemics, and public choice. Public Choice, October. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-023-01104-6

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murtough, P. Condensed history of the great yellow fever epidemic of 1878; personal sketches and incidents, full particulars of the Father Matthew Camp, list of cities and towns visited by the scourge, and names of the victims of the fever in Memphis. Memphis. https://collections.nlm.nih.gov/catalog/nlm:nlmuid-65030310R-bk

  • Nuwer, D. (2009). Plague among the Magnolias: The 1878 Yellow Fever epidemic in Mississippi. University of Alabama Press.

  • Olson, M. (1993). Dictatorship, democracy, and development. The American Political Science Review, 87(3), 567–576.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: The evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge University Press.

  • Paniagua, P. (2022). Elinor Ostrom and public health. Economy and Society, 51(2), 211–234.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Paniagua, P., & Rayamajhee, V. (2022). A Polycentric approach for pandemic governance: Nested externalities and co-production challenges. Journal of Institutional Economics, 18(4), 537–552.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Paniagua, P., & Rayamajhee, V. (2023). On the nature and structure of externalities. Public Choice, July. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-023-01098-1

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parish, R. (1992). Aids and ‘Market Failure.’ Economic Record, 68(3), 278–280.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Philipson, T. (2000). Economic Epidemiology and Infectious Diseases. In Handbook of Health Economics, 1:1761–99. Elsevier.

  • Philipson, T. J., & Posner, R. A. (1993). Private choices and public health: The AIDS epidemic in an economic perspective. Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Piano, E. (2019). State capacity and public choice: A critical survey. Public Choice, 178, 289–309.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Porter, D. (1998). Health, civilization and the state: A history of public health from ancient to modern times. Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Power, J. L. (1879). The epidemic of 1878 in Mississippi: Report of the Yellow Fever relief work. http://resource.nlm.nih.gov/65030600R

  • Price, P. (2016). Epidemics, outsiders, and local protection: Federalism theater in the era of the shotgun quarantine. University of Pennsylvania Journal of Constitutional Law, 19(2), 369–429.

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Rayamajhee, V., & Paniagua, P. (2022). Coproduction and the crafting of cognitive institutions during the COVID-19 pandemic. Journal of Institutional Economics, 18(6), 961–967.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roberts, J. A. (Ed.). (2006). The economics of infectious disease. Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sandler, T. (1992). Collective action: Theory and applications. University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Skarbek, D. (2020). The puzzle of prison order: Why life behind bars varies around the world. Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Skarbek, E. (2014). The Chicago Fire of 1871: A bottom-up approach to disaster relief. Public Choice, 160, 155–180.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stanton, W. (1952). The Irish of Memphis. The West Tennessee Historical Society Papers, 6, 87.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tognotti, E. (2013). Lessons from the history of quarantine, from Plague to Influenza A. Emerging Infectious Diseases, 19(2), 254–259.

    Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  • Trantidis, A. (2023). Government externalities. Public Choice. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-023-01068-7

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Troesken, W. (2015). The pox of liberty: How the Constitution left Americans rich, free, and prone to infection. University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1969). Social cost and government action. The American Economic Review, 59(2), 189–197.

    Google Scholar 

  • Uselton, D. (1996). Irish immigration and settlement in Memphis, Tennessee: 1820’s-1860’s. The West Tennessee Historical Society Papers, 50, 115–129.

    Google Scholar 

  • Waring, G. (1881). The sewerage of Memphis, U.S.A. London: The Sanitary Institute of Great Britain. https://memphislibrary.contentdm.oclc.org/digital/collection/p13039coll5/id/2079/rec/69.

  • Williamson, O. E. (1999). The mechanisms of governance. Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Winslow, C. (1920). The untilled fields of public health. Science, 51(1306), 23–33.

    Article  ADS  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Winston, K. (2020). Yellow Jack’s wrath: The 1878 Yellow Fever epidemic and public health in Mississippi. The Journal of the Southern Association for the History of Medicine and Science, 2(1), 19–42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wrenn, L. B. (1988). ‘Get the City out of the Mud and Mire’, Financing street improvements in post-Civil War Memphis. Tennessee Historical Quarterly, 47(1), 17–26.

    Google Scholar 

  • Young, J. P., & James, A. R. (1912). Standard history of Memphis, Tennessee: From a study of the original sources. H. W. Crew.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I am grateful to Christopher Coyne and Art Carden for their helpful comments on several drafts. Participants in the 2015 graduate student paper workshop at the Mercatus Center at George Mason University, the 2022 Economics and History of Health Crises workshop at Queen’s University Belfast, and the 2022 Markets and Society panel on Institutions and Public Health provided valuable insights. Ilia Murtazashvili, Veeshan Rayamajhee, and Pablo Paniagua Prieto, editors of this special issue, and reviewers all provided helpful comments and support. The librarians of the Memphis and Shelby County Room at the Memphis Public Library provided helpful assistance accessing their yellow fever collection. I am also grateful for the support of Ryan Yonk and the American Institute for Economic Research, where I revised this paper as a visiting fellow during the summer of 2023.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Byron Carson.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Epidemiology of yellow fever

See Fig. 2 and Tables 3, 4.

Fig. 2
figure 2

The Yellow Fever epidemic in Memphis, 1878. Note: Figure shows the death roll of Keating (1879: 209–238) number of daily reported deaths from yellow fever and a 7-day rolling average between August and December 1878

Table 3 The largest yellow fever outbreaks in 1878
Table 4 Yellow fever epidemics in Memphis, 1828 to 1879

Appendix 2: Reports on flight from yellow fever

In Grenada, MS, “All that could hurried away” (Smith via Keating, 1879: 377). J. B. Townsend noted that around August 16, one week after the first death, Grenada was almost depopulated (Smith’s report in Keating, 1879: 379). Keating (1879: 174) provides one of the earliest accounts of the “hegira” from Memphis. After a short-lived municipal quarantine imposed on July 27, telegrams about yellow fever in Grenada, MS, on August 11, the announcement of the first case in Memphis around August 13, and subsequent cases and deaths over the next couple of days, people in Memphis began to leave the city. Keating (1879: 147) states that “The trains on the Charleston and Louisville Railroads, as a consequence, went out crowded, and every seat and berth was taken for the trains on both roads for the next two days.” Keating estimates that 15,000 to 20,000 people fled by August 18. To facilitate this exodus, Keating (1879: 183) notes the rise in pawning, e.g., of watches, diamonds, and silver spoons, as well as bank withdrawals. People also “rapidly occupied” homes in the suburbs of the town (Memphis Daily Appeal, August 16, 1878). Following Keating’s (1879: 183) remarks on pawning, he states, “Lengthy, populous streets in Memphis were left without a dozen families residing thereon. The occupants disappeared as if by magic. Some streets were wholly deserted by their white inhabitants, only colored servants—not deemed liable to the disease—remaining.” In late September, Thomas Porteous saw that much of the area between Louisville and New Orleans was desolate (Ellis, 1992). Atlanta received approximately 3000 refugees between August 1 and the end of October, presumably from many cities throughout the southern United States (Ellis, 1992).

Appendix 3: Public notices in Memphis

August 16

Citizens’ Meeting To-Day

The undersigned citizens, who intend to remain in the city during the prevalence of the fever, invite all of our people similarly inclined to meet at the Greenlaw Opera House at eleven o’clock, for consultation and action with regard to assisting each other through the scourge, and providing ways and means for removing form the city to a place of safety such of our people as are pecuniarily unable to do so without assistance. It is expected that answers to telegrams sent to President Hayes will be placed before the meeting.

Source: Keating (1879: 390)

August 24

The Father Matthew Camp

Is established. It is for the benefit, first, of the members and families of the Father Matthew society; second, as far as its means shall permit, for all Catholics who are in danger of contracting the fever, and also for all in need of protection from the fever. No persons shall be admitted who have not permits. Permits may be secured by applying at St. Bridget’s, St. Peter’s and St. Patrick’s churches. All who are admitted to the camp will have to submit to its rules and regulations. So far, we have been giving free transportation to all, and providing for their every necessity. We have already provided for about one hundred and ten persons. We have received no assistance from abroad as yet. The camp is on Cyprus creek, on Fontaine & Co.’s place. Mr. Consadine is in charge. The priests of St. Bridget’s shall attend it regularly. Holy mass will be celebrated there to-morrow at nine o’clock. The whole camp regulations are under the charge of the Father Matthew society. Until a certain number of days shall have elapsed, no one shall be given a permanent place. Dr. Cavanagh is the attending physician.

W. Walsh,

President

Source: Memphis Daily Appeal, August 24, 1878.

Appendix 4: Municipal debt and public health in Memphis, TN, 1850 to 1880

Municipal state capacity in Memphis varied, but it was rarely sufficient to clarify, finance, and enforce public health rules between the late 1860s and 1878. The city’s original charter of 1826—and revisions in 1867—states the government’s legitimate public health powers, i.e., “free power and authority to enact and pass all by-laws and ordinances necessary and proper to preserve the health of the town” (Bridges, 1867: 73 and 201). The city’s fiscal state capacity began to deteriorate in the 1850s because city leaders began to issue over 1000 bonds for various railroad endeavors, grading and graveling projects, cash, and for indebtedness, which added over $1 million to municipal debt (Keating & Vedder, 1888: 350). In 1860, Young and James (1912) note poor management, indignant citizens, and a debt of $596,742. The city’s bonded or long-term debt continued to increase because of tax delinquencies, cash shortages, disruptions from the civil war, and intermittent financial crises (Wrenn, 1988). By 1877, the city government held assets of $882,488 and debts of approximately $4,500,000. Deficit spending was common for similarly sized cities in the 1850s and 1870s, but was peculiar for southern cities (Legler et al., 1988).

The Civil War and reconstruction each had negative marginal effects on the city’s legal and financial state capacity. At the onset of the Civil War, a band of 700 vigilantes, known as the Committee of Safety, the minute men, and/or the vigilance committee, discouraged union sympathies within local and state officials; the Confederate Congress also acquired debts to northern creditors and requested a cessation of courts for 12 months; after the ratification of secession in June 1861, the Tennessee legislature requested that courts delay cases involving debts (Keating & Vedder, 1888; Lanier, 2012). During the spring of 1862, Memphis courts ceased operations, and the city was placed under a combination of martial law, rule by the Union Army, and/or military and civil commissions until fall 1864. Such factors would have blemished the legitimacy of the city’s legal system and its ability to protect property rights. Even city leaders and police officers varied in their legitimacy and willingness to uphold their duty, which became apparent during the 1866 race riots (Carden and Coyne 2013). Still, during the war, many advocated for the resumption of the city’s laws and police enforcement, and the city had acquired a growing legal community and a bar association (Lanier, 2012).

Tennessee avoided some of the harms associated with military and radical Reconstruction, in part, because ex-Confederate soldiers and sympathizers had been disenfranchised. With a Republican-controlled state government, the state legislature ratified the 13th and 14th Amendments, they repealed their ordinance of secession, and rejoined the Union in 1866. The value of real and personal property indicates that Memphians might have quickly recovered from the war if it hadn’t been for the 1867 yellow fever epidemic and occasional fires. Such values were approximately $16.8 million in 1860; they fell to a low of $15 million in 1864, increased to a peak of $30.8 million in 1867, and fell to $24.7 million in 1870 (Young & James, 1912: 153).

After the city regained its government, its state capacity seems to have been trending upwards. In 1870, for example, the city government added a common council, which became a part of the general council, along with the mayor and board of aldermen; each ward elected one alderman for a two-year period and two councilmen for a one-year period. Following Piano (2019), these entities provided some intragovernmental competition and could have encouraged local politicians to improve governance. That is, they could have made improvements if it weren’t for the city’s debts. Additional spending, e.g., on public health, would have stretched city budgets and debts further, and it might have incurred the displeasure of citizens, especially wealthier merchants, homeowners, and taxpayers. Such motives make more sense considering (1) falling price levels during the 1870s, which indicate higher real costs of borrowing and higher tax burdens, and (2) falling cotton prices and growing competition from rail transportation, which would have lowered incomes for many merchants in Memphis (Burdekin & Siklos, 2013; Clotfelter, 1973). Thus, paying down the city’s debt obligations, reforming the structure of city government to prevent excessive spending, and limiting future tax burdens became valuable ends people wanted elected officials to pursue. In an address to the general council, Mayor Flippin is reported to have said that funding the city debt was “our only present salvation” (Memphis Daily Appeal, June 11, 1878).

Merchants and wealthier citizens were growing in their concern about the city’s debt. Generally, merchants advocated for a so-called business-like government, and many formed minor, albeit vocal groups to constrain city leaders and their spending (Clotfelter, 1973). More explicitly, jurists, lawyers, merchants, and concerned citizens inquired about abolishing the city government in the late 1860s, but such goals never advanced until the late 1870s and after the yellow fever epidemics of 1878–1879. For example, a bill to repeal the city’s charter was read to a joint meeting of the Chamber of Commerce and the Cotton Exchange in February 1877, which did not pass (Bejach 1950). These debt and financing problems, along with the desire to abolish the city government entirely, led local citizens to petition the state government to abolish its municipal charter. The request was granted in 1879 and the area became a taxing district until 1891 (Bejach 1950).

Related to and because of the city’s debt problems, the city government faced legal challenges to its authority to tax and finance public health-related goods. In 1871, for example, the city had its right to build a waterworks system revoked by the Tennessee supreme court. As the city had not built a waterworks and had not made plans to do so, the state legislature granted a corporate charter to the Memphis Water Co., a private firm (see Memphis v. Memphis Water Co., 52 Tenn. 495). Local and state courts also issued writs of mandamus that compelled the city to pay parties who had provided services related to paving and stone work. An 1872 Tennessee Supreme court case limited the city’s ability to collect taxes, which led to property owners requesting relief for expenses already incurred (Wrenn, 1988). In reference to the 1873 epidemic, Dr. Mallory, a former member of the board of health, states:

It is true the streets were not as clean as they should have been, that the back alleys were much neglected at a time when the health of the city seemed to demand the greatest cleanliness. The garbage from private houses, and especially from public boarding houses, was not removed with the expedition that was proper under the circumstances…two things must be remembered – the epidemic was not yet developed, and the city treasury was not encumbered by a very large amount of money. Within the last few years extensive and costly improvements have been made at the expense of the city government, all of which are in the highest degree important as sanitary agents, and for which the city is still in debt. (Mallory, 1874: 356)

Mallory’s statement belies a belief that sanitation is a primary means of prevention. Despite some improvements in public health, people were allowed to pollute unimpeded. Young and James (1912: 163) suggest that such improvements were less helpful due to lax enforcement:

After the experience of 1873, the place should have been put in thorough sanitary condition, but as one summer passed after another and the fever did not return, premises, alleys, vacant lots and other localities became unclean and general neglect grew from bad to worse with only an occasional spurt of activity on the part of the Board of Health.

After the 1878 and 1879 epidemics, Waring suggests that the Gayoso bayou was an “eroded channel of a stream ordinarily small, but, under occasional sudden showers, subject to an enormous increase in volume. Its sides are steep and irregular, and its depth is quite uniformly from 12 to 15 feet below the general level of its banks” (Waring, 1881: 3). Privies of local residences and commercial buildings—there were 5914 by 1879—drained into places such as the Gayoso bayou, which became pools of standing waste by the 1870s; there were also 84 cesspools in 1879 (Annual Report of the National Board of Health, 1879; Capers, 1938). Capers (1938: 458) claims that sanitation in Memphis was no better than the “poorest medieval borough.” Poor sanitation also contributed to the yellow fever and cholera outbreaks of 1873 (Bruesch, 1952).

Mortality rates also indicate the ineffectual health department, in addition to the many other factors that negatively influenced health in the nineteenth century—for example, population growth put more people and diseases together, and the germ theory of disease was still developing. Comparing the lower urban mortality rates in the early 1850s with the higher rates in the 1870s, shown in Fig. 3 and Table 5, reveals a stark difference in the health of the city.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Overall mortality rate in Memphis, monthly, 1851 to 1853. Note: Keating and Vedder (1888: 341). Assumes a mean population between 1850 and 1854 of 10,764

Table 5 Major causes of mortality in Memphis, 1875 to 1879

With population growth and the commensurate nuisances that arise, e.g., there were 3000 dray carts in 1871 (Wrenn, 1988), local cemetery records indicate there were 46 deaths per 1000 people in 1872 (Ellis, 1974). Depending on the source, Memphis had 23–33 deaths per 1000, one of the highest mortality rates in 1875 (Annual Report of the National Board of Health, 1879; Harris, 1875). Such data suggest that health in Memphis was poor but perhaps not unusually poor (on the nineteenth-century urban mortality penalty, see Bleakley et al., 2018). Table 6 presents urban mortality rates in Memphis and cities of comparable size.

Table 6 Urban mortality rates in cities of comparable size to Memphis, 1873 and 1875

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Carson, B. Prevention externalities: private and public responses to the 1878 yellow fever epidemic. Public Choice (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-023-01142-0

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-023-01142-0

Keywords

Navigation